文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › Idiosyncratic risk and the cross-section of expected stock returns

Idiosyncratic risk and the cross-section of expected stock returns

Managing Editor:G. WILLIAM SCHWERT Founding Editor:MICHAEL C. JENSEN Advisory Editors:EUGENE F . FAMA KENNETH FRENCH WAYNE MIKKELSON

JAY SHANKEN ANDREI SHLEIFER CLIFFORD W. SMITH, JR.

RENé M. STULZ Associate Editors:

HENDRIK BESSEMBINDER

JOHN CAMPBELL HARRY DeANGELO DARRELL DUFFIE BENJAMIN ESTY RICHARD GREEN JARRAD HARFORD

AUL HEAL CHRISTOPHER JAMES

SIMON JOHNSON STEVEN KAPLAN TIM LOUGHRAN MICHELLE LOWRY KEVIN MURPHY MICAH OFFICER LUBOS P ASTOR NEIL PEARSON

JAY RITTER RICHARD GREEN RICHARD SLOAN JEREMY C. STEIN JERRY WARNER MICHAEL WEISBACH

KAREN WRUCK

Idiosyncratic risk and the cross-section of expected stock returns $

Fangjian Fu ?

Singapore Management University,Lee Kong Chian,School of Business,50Stamford Road,Singapore 178899,Singapore

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:

Received 5July 2007Received in revised form 14January 2008

Accepted 12February 2008

Available online 5November 2008JEL classi?cation:G12C53

Keywords:

Idiosyncratic risk

Cross-sectional returns Time-varying GARCH

a b s t r a c t

Theories such as Merton [1987.A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information.Journal of Finance 42,483–510]predict a positive relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return when investors do not diversify their portfolio.Ang,Hodrick,Xing,and Zhang [2006.The cross-section of volatility and expected returns.Journal of Finance 61,259–299],however,?nd that monthly stock returns are negatively related to the one-month lagged idiosyncratic volatilities.I show that idiosyncratic volatilities are time-varying and thus,their ?ndings should not be used to imply the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,ing the exponential GARCH models to estimate expected idiosyncratic volatilities,I ?nd a signi?cantly positive relation between the estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatilities and expected returns.Further evidence suggests that Ang et al.’s ?ndings are largely explained by the return reversal of a subset of small stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities.

&2008Elsevier B.V.All rights reserved.

1.Introduction

Modern portfolio theory suggests that investors hold a portfolio of stocks to diversify idiosyncratic risk.The capital asset pricing model (CAPM)builds on the portfolio theory and predicts that all investors hold the market portfolio in equilibrium.As a result,only systematic risk is priced in equilibrium and idiosyncratic risk is not.

For various reasons,however,investors in reality may not hold perfectly diversi?ed portfolios.For instance,Goetzmann and Kumar (2004)show that,based on a sample of more than 62,000household investors in the period of 1991–1996,more than 25%of the investor portfolios contain only one stock,over half of the investor portfolios contain no more than three stocks,and less than 10%of the investor portfolios contain more than 10stocks.After examining the standard deviation of portfolio returns,Campbell,Lettau,Malkiel,and Xu (2001,p.25)suggest that ‘‘the number of randomly selected stocks needed to achieve relatively complete portfolio diversi?-cation’’is about 50.

Various theories assuming under-diversi?cation pre-dict that idiosyncratic risk is positively related to the expected stock returns in the cross section.Among them are Levy (1978),Merton (1987),and Malkiel and Xu (2002).Under-diversi?ed investors demand a return compensation for bearing idiosyncratic risk.But a recent paper by Ang,Hodrick,Xing,and Zhang (2006,AHXZ hereafter)?nds that,in the cross-section of stocks,high idiosyncratic volatility in one month predicts abysmally low average returns in the next month,which they call

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

journal homepage:https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,/locate/jfec

Journal of Financial Economics

0304-405X/$-see front matter &2008Elsevier B.V.All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.j?neco.2008.02.003

$

I thank Turan Bali,Mike Barclay,Charles Cao,Joe Chen,Tarun Chordia,Jin-Chuan Duan,Bruno Gerard,Ludger Hentschel,Harrison Hong,Chuan-Yang Hwang,Tim Johnson,Roger Loh,John Long,Yuanzhi Luo,Lubos Pastor,Jeff Pontiff,Carmela Quintos,Jay Ritter,Bill Schwert (the editor),Maria Schutte,Cliff Smith,Chong Wang,Jiang Wang,Xiaotong Wang,Yuhang Xing,Yexiao Xu,Wei Yang,Jun Yu,Xiaoyan Zhang,Lu Zhang,Zhe Zhang,and seminar participants at Peking University,Singapore Management University,University of Rochester,the 2005European Finance Association Meeting,the 2006Eastern Finance Association (EFA)Meeting,the 2006Western Finance Associa-tion (WFA)Meeting,and especially,the anonymous referee for helpful comments.I acknowledge the best paper award from the EFA and the NYSE student travel grant from the WFA.?Tel.:+6568280244;fax:+6568280427.E-mail address:fjfu@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,.sg Journal of Financial Economics 91(2009)24–37

‘‘a substantive puzzle.’’Their study poses three important questions:(1)Do the?ndings imply that the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return is nega-tive?(2)If not necessary,what is the true empirical relation?(3)If the true relation is not negative,how their ?ndings are explained?

I attempt to answer these three questions in this paper. The sample of data includes stocks traded on the NYSE, Amex,and Nasdaq during the period from July1963to December2006.I?rst identify that idiosyncratic volati-lities,unlike some?rm characteristics,are very volatile over time.For an average individual stock,the standard deviation of its monthly idiosyncratic volatilities is55% of the mean.In order to explain expected returns,the theoretically correct variable should be the expected idiosyncratic volatilities in the same period that the expected returns are measured.Since idiosyncratic volatilities are time-varying,the one-month lagged idio-syncratic volatility may not be an appropriate proxy for the expected idiosyncratic volatility of this month.Indeed, the average?rst-order autocorrelation of idiosyncratic volatility is only0.33in my sample.Dickey-Fuller tests further show that,for nine out of10stocks,their idiosyncratic volatility does not follow a random walk process.These?ndings suggest that the negative relation between the lagged idiosyncratic volatility and average returns in AHXZ(2006)does not imply that the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return is nega-tive.The lagged idiosyncratic volatility might not be a good estimate of expected idiosyncratic volatility.

In order to capture the time-varying property of idiosyncratic risk,I employ the exponential generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity(EGARCH) models and out-of-sample data to estimate expected idiosyncratic volatilities.I then run Fama-MacBeth regres-sions of monthly stock returns on the EGARCH estimates and other?rm characteristics that are known to explain cross-sectional returns.I?nd that returns are positively related to the EGARCH-estimated conditional idiosyn-cratic volatilities.The positive relation is both statistically and economically signi?cant.On average,a stock that has a conditional idiosyncratic volatility of one standard deviation higher than other stock earns a return of about 1%higher in a month.The coef?cient of determination for the cross-sectional regressions also increases signi?cantly after including the conditional idiosyncratic volatility.

A zero-investment portfolio that is long in the10%of the highest and short in the10%of the lowest conditional idiosyncratic volatilities earns a positive return of1.75%in a month.These?ndings support the theory prediction that idiosyncratic risk is positively related to expected returns.

However,AHXZ’s(2006)?nding that stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities tend to have abnormally low returns in the subsequent month is still puzzling, especially given that the contemporaneous relation between return and volatility is signi?cantly positive.

I show that their results can largely be explained by the return reversal of stocks with high idiosyncratic volati-lities.Speci?cally,stocks with high idiosyncratic volati-lities are shown to have high contemporaneous returns.The positive abnormal returns tend to reverse,resulting in negative abnormal returns in the following month.1 Moreover,these stocks are small in size.The40%of stocks with the highest idiosyncratic volatilities only contribute to9%of the total market capitalization.Since transaction costs for small?rms are notoriously high,and idiosyn-cratic risk increases holding costs and makes arbitrage more costly(Pontiff,2006),it is dubious that the negative relation would present a true pro?table opportunity.2 AHXZ’s(2006)?ndings have attracted much attention recently.Bali and Cakici(2008)suggest that AHXZ’s results are sensitive to:(i)data frequency used to estimate idiosyncratic volatility,(ii)weighting schemes used to compute average portfolio returns,(iii)breakpoints utilized to sort stocks into quintile portfolios,and(iv) using a screen for size,price,and liquidity,and therefore are not robust.Huang,Liu,Rhee,and Zhang(2007)point out that AHXZ’s results are driven by monthly stock return reversals.After controlling for the difference in the past-month returns,the negative relation between average return and the lagged idiosyncratic volatility disappears. Using a different method that more closely focuses on AHXZ’s?ndings,I point to the same conclusion.Boyer, Mitton,and Vorkink(2007)suggest that idiosyncratic volatility is a good predictor of expected skewness—an explanatory variable of cross-sectional returns(Harvey and Siddique,2000).The negative relation greatly reduces after controlling for expected skewness.Jiang,Xu,and Yao (2006)argue that high idiosyncratic volatility and low future returns are both related to a lack of information disclosure among?rms with poor earnings prospects. Investors underreact to earnings information in idiosyn-cratic volatility.

In their more recent work,Ang,Hodrick,Xing,and Zhang(2008)?nd that the negative relation between average return and the lagged idiosyncratic volatility also exists in other G7countries.However,Brockman and Schutte(2007)follow my EGARCH method to estimate conditional idiosyncratic volatility and con?rm that the relation between stock return and conditional idiosyn-cratic volatility is also positive in international data. Similarly Spiegel and Wang(2006)and Eiling(2006) adopt the EGARCH models to estimate conditional idiosyncratic volatility and both?nd the positive relation in the U.S.data.Spiegel and Wang also show that idiosyncratic volatility swamped liquidity in explaining the cross-sectional variation of average returns but not vice versa.Eiling shows that the idiosyncratic risk premium is related to hedging demand due to investors’non-tradable human capital.Chua,Goh,and Zhang(2007) model idiosyncratic volatility as an AR(2)process and 1In order to be consistent with AHXZ(2006)for a better comparison,I also use the Fama-French three-factor model as the benchmark model for expected returns.AHXZ’s arguments are mainly based on the portfolio of the highest idiosyncratic volatility that yields a negative abnormal return in the following month.

2In their more recent work,AHXZ(2006)admit that their documented negative relation implies‘‘not necessarily a relation that involves expected volatility’’but argue that it suggests a pro?table trading strategy.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3725

decompose it into expected and unexpected components. Controlling for the unexpected idiosyncratic volatility, they also?nd the relation between expected return and expected idiosyncratic volatility is signi?cantly positive.

The reminder of the paper proceeds as follows.In Section2,I measure monthly idiosyncratic volatility, examine its time-series properties,and estimate the one-month-ahead conditional idiosyncratic volatilities using EGARCH models.In Section3,I examine the cross-sectional relation between conditional idiosyncratic vola-tilities and expected returns.I replicate and explain AHXZ’s(2006)?ndings in Section4.Section5concludes.

2.Idiosyncratic volatility and its time-series property

The goal of the paper is to examine whether under-diversi?ed investors are compensated for bearing idiosyn-cratic risk.From the theory perspective,the risk and return tradeoff should be contemporaneous.Investors earn returns for bearing the risk in the same period. Therefore if idiosyncratic volatility,as a natural proxy for idiosyncratic risk,is priced,we expect to observe a positive empirical relation between expected return and expected idiosyncratic volatility.However,neither expected return nor expected idiosyncratic risk is ob-servable.A conventional practice is to use the realized return as the dependent variable in cross-sectional regressions where the realized return is assumed to be the sum of the expected return and a random error.3 The expected idiosyncratic volatility and other control variables are put on the right-hand side of the regressions.

R it?g0ttg1t E tà1?IVOL it t

X K

k?2g

kt

E tà1?X kit t it

i?1;2;...;N t;t?1;2;...;T.(1) The dependent variable is the realized returns for stock i in period t.E tà1?á stands for the function of expectation conditional on the information set at tà1.IVOL it represents the idiosyncratic volatility of stock i during period t.

E tà1?IVOL it is the expected idiosyncratic volatility for stock i at time t conditional on the information set at time tà1.X kit represents other explanatory variables of cross-sectional returns.N t is the total number of stocks at t,and T is the total number of time periods.The null hypothesis is g1t?0,that is,idiosyncratic risk is not priced.Existing theories assuming under-diversi?cation such as Merton(1987)predict that g1t40.

It is crucial to have a quality estimate of E tà1?IVOL it —the expected idiosyncratic volatility.If idiosyncratic risk is highly persistent as following a random walk process,we can simply use the lagged value as an estimate of the expected value.In this case,idiosyncratic risk resembles some?rm characteristics such as size and the market-to-book ratio of equity.Fama and French(1992),for example, use market capitalizations and book-to-market equity ratios of the current year to explain the cross-sectional variation of monthly returns in the next year.However,we have no prior reasons to presume high persistence in idiosyncratic risk.Idiosyncratic risk re?ects?rm-speci?c information that is volatile in its nature.Many factors could contribute to the time-varying nature of?rm-speci?c information.For instance,disclosure of earnings information is periodical and infrequent;the supply and demand of certain?rms are subject to seasonal variations; competitors’moves may also bring impact on the?rm’s pro?tability.I examine the time-series property of idiosyncratic volatility in this section.The results indeed suggest that idiosyncratic volatility varies substantially over time.Therefore,a quality estimate of conditional idiosyncratic volatility is demanded to draw an appro-priate inference on the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return.

2.1.Estimation of idiosyncratic volatility

Idiosyncratic risk is de?ned as the risk that is unique to a speci?c?rm,so it is also called?rm-speci?c risk.By de?nition,idiosyncratic risk is independent of the com-mon movement of the market.Following AHXZ(2006), I measure the idiosyncratic risk of an individual stock as follows.In every month,daily excess returns of individual stocks are regressed on the daily Fama-French(1993,1996) three factors:(i)the excess return on a broad market portfolioeR màr fT,(ii)the difference between the return on a portfolio of small stocks and the return on a portfolio of large stocks(SMB,small minus big),and(iii)the difference between the return on a portfolio of high book-to-market stocks and the return on a portfolio of low book-to-market stocks(HML,high minus low),

R i tàr t?a ittb iteR m tàr tTts it SMB tth it HML tt i t.(2) t is the subscript for the day and t is the subscript for the month,t2t,and b i,s i,and h i are factor sensitivities or loadings.Daily stock returns are obtained from the Center for Research in Security Prices(CRSP).I include stocks traded on the NYSE,Amex,or Nasdaq during the period of July1963to December2006.The daily factor data are downloaded from Kenneth R.French’s Web site.4 I perform a time-series regression for each stock in each month.The idiosyncratic volatility of a stock is computed as the standard deviation of the regression residuals.To reduce the impact of infrequent trading on idiosyncratic volatility estimates,I require a minimum of15trading days in a month for which CRSP reports both a daily return and non-zero trading volume.5Moreover,I transform the standard deviation of daily return residuals to a monthly return residual by multiplying the daily standard deviation by the square root of the number of trading days in that month.6In the pooled sample of2,946,521

3See,for example,Fama and French(1992),Chordia,Subrahma-nyam,and Anshuman(2001),and Easley,Hvidkjaer,and O’Hara(2002), among others.

4https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_ library.html.I thank Kenneth French for making these data available.

5The trading days per month in my sample ranges from15to23 days with a mean and median of21days.Only about1%of?rm-month observations have fewer than19trading days.

6A similar procedure is used by French,Schwert,and Stambaugh (1987)and Schwert(1989).

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–37 26

?rm-month observations,the mean monthly idiosyncratic volatility(IVOL)is14.17%with a standard deviation of 13.91%.

2.2.Time-series property of idiosyncratic volatility

Table1presents the time-series property of individual stock idiosyncratic volatilities.I?rst compute the time-series statistics of idiosyncratic volatility for each?rm and then summarize the mean statistics across about26,000?rms in the sample.The time-series mean IVOL is on average16.87%across stocks and the mean standard deviation is9.94%.The mean coef?cient of variation is 0.55,indicating that the standard deviation of IVOL for an average stock is55%of its time-series mean.This suggests that individual stock idiosyncratic volatilities vary sub-stantially over time.The last columns report the auto-correlations of IVOLs.The mean autocorrelation is0.33at the?rst lag and decays slowly.I also report the statistics of the changes in the logarithm of the idiosyncratic volatilityeLneIVOL t=IVOL tà1TT.The autocorrelation of this new variable isà0.42at the?rst lag and close to zero at lags of higher orders.This evidence suggests that the?rst differences of LneIVOL tTfor quite a few?rms might follow a?rst-order moving average process.

AHXZ(2006)draw expected return implications on the basis of the observed relation between monthly stock returns and the one-month lagged IVOL.Their empirical methods implicitly assume that the time-series idiosyn-cratic volatility can be approximated by a random walk process.The?rst-order autocorrelation for a random walk process should be one,and the?rst differences of a random walk are a white noise and therefore the autocorrelation should be zero at all lags.The autocorrela-tion evidence in Table1suggests that the random walk hypothesis is not appropriate for a typical stock’s idiosyncratic volatility process.To illustrate this point further,I run the following time-series regression for each stock,

IVOL i;tt1àIVOL i;t?g0itg1i IVOL i;ttZ i,

t?1;2;...T;i?1;2;...;N.(3) The coef?cient g1i should be indistinguishable from zero if the time-series of IVOL it follows a random walk.This is a standard unit-root test.For each time series of IVOL,I estimate the coef?cient g1i and then compare its t-statistic with the Dickey-Fuller critical values for the unit-root tests.In Table2,I report the cross-?rm mean,median, the lower and upper quartiles of the g1i estimates,and the associated t-statistics.The last column reports the percentage of?rms for which the random walk hypothesis is rejected at the1%level.For the purpose of regressions, I require?rms to have at least30months of consecutive observations(T i X30for every stock).7This requirement reduces the number of?rms to20,979.The mean g1i among these?rms isà0.61and the mean t-statistic of g1i isà6.81.According to the Dickey-Fuller critical values of t-statistics(Fuller,1996),I reject the null hypothesis of a random walk in90%of the?rms.Examinations on Ln(IVOL)yield very similar results,which are also reported in Table2.The results suggest that it is not appropriate to describe a typical stock’s idiosyncratic volatility process as a random walk.8Put differently,using this month’s idiosyncratic volatility to approximate the value in the next month could introduce severe measurement errors. As a result,AHXZ’s(2006)?ndings should not be used to draw inference on the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return.

2.3.Estimation of expected idiosyncratic volatility

In order to examine the relation between expected return and expected idiosyncratic volatility,we need a better model to capture the time-varying property of idiosyncratic volatility.I resort to the EGARCH models to achieve this goal.

Engle(1982)proposes the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity(ARCH)model to represent a series with changing volatility.It proves to be an effective tool in modeling time-series behavior of many economic vari-ables,especially?nancial market data.The ARCH model is

Table1

Time-series properties of idiosyncratic volatility.

This table summarizes the time-series statistics of individual stock idiosyncratic volatilities.I?rst compute the time-series statistics of idiosyncratic volatility for each stock and then the mean statistics across all stocks.Stocks are traded in the NYSE,Amex,or Nasdaq during July1963to December2006. The idiosyncratic volatility(IVOL)is estimated as follows.In every month,excess daily returns of each individual stock are regressed on the daily Fama-French three factors:RmRf,SMB,and HML.The(monthly)idiosyncratic volatility of the stock is the product of the standard deviation of the regression residuals and the square root of the number of observations in the month.

N Mean S.D. C.V.Skew Autocorrelation at lags

123456111213

IVOL26,18916.879.940.55 1.650.330.270.240.200.190.180.120.140.11

Ln

IVOL t

IVOL tà1

26,068à0.0040.54366.24à0.03à0.42à0.040.01à0.02à0.010.01à0.020.03à0.02

7The results are robust to setting T412or T424.

8Cross-sectional return studies often use the lagged variables of

?rm characteristics to explain future returns.For example,Fama and

French(1992)use market capitalization and the book-to-market equity

ratio of the current year to explain the cross-sectional returns in the next

year.The underlying justi?cation for this practice is that these?rm

characteristics are fairly persistent.I perform the same unit-root test on

the process of?rm market capitalization and indeed,am not able to

reject the null hypothesis of random walk in98%of the observations.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3727

attractive because the variance and the mean process are estimated jointly.Applying to stock market returns,it implicitly assumes that investors update their estimates of the mean and variance of returns each period using the newly revealed surprises in last period’s returns.Bollerslev (1986)extends the ARCH model to GARCH (generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasti-city)model.The GARCH model provides a more ?exible framework to capture the dynamic structure of condi-tional variances (volatilities).A step further,Nelson (1991)proposes an EGARCH model to catch the asymmetric property of volatility,namely that the return volatility increases after a stock price drop.This phenomenon is also called ‘‘leverage effects’’because the drop of stock price mechanically increases the leverage ratio and thus the risk of the ?rm.

GARCH models have been widely used to model the conditional volatility of returns.For example,French,Schwert,and Stambaugh (1987)model the market volatility by a GARCH (1,2)process and ?nd that the market risk premium is positively related to the condi-tional market volatility.Bollerslev,Engle,and Wooldridge (1988)use a multivariate GARCH model to demonstrate time-varying risk premiums.GARCH models are of various types.My objective is to select a GARCH model that well describes the time-series idiosyncratic volatility of in-dividual stock returns.Pioneered by Pagan and Schwert (1990),studies have suggested a number of approaches to compare alternative GARCH (and non-parametric)speci-?cations.Pagan and Schwert ?t a number of different models to monthly U.S.stock returns and ?nd that Nelson’s (1991)EGARCH model is the best in overall performance.Engle and Mustafa (1992)assess the speci?cation of conditional variance models based on

the observed prices for stock options.Speci?cally they use the option prices to compute the implied variances,which are then regarded as the benchmark for the estimates from various time-series models.They ?nd that simple GARCH and EGARCH models perform the best among their selected time-series models.Emphasizing the importance of the asymmetry of the volatility response to news,Engle and Ng (1993)test the speci?cations of various volatility models using Lagrange Multiplier tests.They also con-clude that Nelson’s EGARCH speci?cation does a good job in capturing the asymmetry of conditional volatilities.In addition,EGARCH models do not need to restrict para-meter values to avoid negative variance as other ARCH and GARCH models do.

Weighing all evidence,I choose to model idiosyncratic volatilities by the EGARCH (p,q )model,in which 1p p p 3,1p q p 3.The explicit functional forms are as follows:R it àr t ?a i tb i eR mt àr t Tts i SMB t th i HML t t it ,

it $N e0;s 2it T,

(4)

ln s 2it

?a i t

X p l ?1

b i ;l ln s

2

i ;t àl

t

X q k ?1

c i ;k

y i ;t àk

s i ;t àk

tg i ;t àk s i ;t àk

àe2=p T1=2

.(5)

I describe the monthly return process by the Fama-French three-factor model as in Eq.(4).The conditional (on the information set at time t à1)distribution of residual it is assumed to be normal with the mean of zero and the variance of s 2it .My objective is to estimate

the conditional variance s 2

it .It is a function of the past p -period of residual variance and q -period of return shocks as speci?ed by Eq.(5).Permutation of these orders

Table 2

Do monthly idiosyncratic volatilities follow a random walk process.

This table presents statistics of the estimations from the time-series regressions in which the changes in idiosyncratic volatility of an individual stock are regressed on the level of idiosyncratic volatility in the past month.The regression is intended to examine whether the time-series idiosyncratic volatilities of this individual stock follows a random walk.The reported statistics are the cross-sectional mean,median,the lower and the upper quartiles of the coef?cient estimate g 1,and its associated t -statistics.The t -statistics are compared with the Dickey-Fuller critical values *to examine whether the null hypothesis of a random walk is rejected.The last column reports the percentage of ?rms for which the random walk hypothesis is rejected at the 1%level.For the regression,I require ?rms to have at least 30months of observations (T i X 308i ).The sample period is July 1963to December 2006.Variables

N

Mean

Median

Q 1

Q 3

RW rejected (%)

Model:IVOL i ;t t1àIVOL i ;t ?g 0i tg 1i IVOL i ;t tZ i ;i ?1;2;...;N ;t ?1;2;...;T i g 120,979à0.61à0.60à0.76

à0.4589.97

t (g 1)20,979à6.81à6.40

à8.43à4.85

Model:LnIVOL i ;t t1àLnIVOL i ;t ?g 0i tg 1i LnIVOL i ;t tZ i ;i ?1;2;...;N ;t ?1;2;...;T i g 120,979à0.56à0.55à0.70à0.4187.81

t (g 1)20,979à6.38à5.99à7.86à4.51

*Dickey-Fuller critical t-statistics (from Fuller,1996)Sample size Critical t-statistics (1%)

25à3.7550à3.59100à3.50250à3.45500

à3.44

F.Fu /Journal of Financial Economics 91(2009)24–37

28

yields nine different EGARCH models:EGARCH(1,1), EGARCH(1,2),EGARCH(1,3),EGARCH(2,1),EGARCH (2,2),EGARCH(2,3),EGARCH(3,1),EGARCH(3,2),and EGARCH(3,3).Each model is employed independently for each individual stock.Therefore,if a stock’s idiosyncratic volatility process as of month t converges under all the nine models,I would have nine estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatilities at month t+1.The estimate generated by the model of the lowest Akaike Information Criterion(AIC)is chosen.9I also require?rms to have at least30monthly returns to be eligible for estimation.

My EGARCH(p,q)model involves p+q+3parameters. Using the full period data to estimate these parameters, though prevalent in early studies,incurs a look-ahead bias.10To avoid this concern,I estimate EGARCH para-meters by using an expanding window of data with a requirement of30minimum observations.In other words, the EGARCH parameters used to forecast conditional idiosyncratic volatility at month t are estimated on the basis of the data up through month tà1.This also applies to the model selection.

The estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatility, denoted by E(IVOL),will be used in the cross-sectional return tests in the next section.The mean E(IVOL)is 12.67%with a standard deviation of10.91%in the pooled sample.The correlation between IVOL and E(IVOL)is0.46 and is statistically signi?cant at the1%level.Empirical evidence con?rms the importance to have more than one lag in estimating E(IVOL).Of all the estimates,only26.67% are yielded by the EGARCH(1,q)models while40%are generated by the EGARCH(3,q)models.In particular, EGARCH(1,1)is the best-?tting model for the fewest number of?rm-month observations(7.41%)and EGARCH (3,1)is the best-?tting model for the most number of observations(16.58%).

3.Cross-sectional return tests

3.1.Data and variables

In this section,I investigate the cross-sectional relation between average stock returns and the estimated condi-tional idiosyncratic volatilities.I examine stocks traded on the NYSE,Amex,and Nasdaq during the period July1963 to December2006—522months in total.The data of monthly stock returns are obtained from CRSP.Table3 presents the variable descriptive statistics of the pooled sample.The mean monthly returns(RET)in my sample period are1.18%and the mean excess return(XRET,raw return net of one-month T-bill rate)is0.71%.11The mean idiosyncratic volatility is14.17%and the mean expected idiosyncratic volatility is12.67%.

Table3

Variable descriptive statistics for the pooled sample:July1963to December2006.

This table reports the pooled descriptive statistics of stocks that are traded in the NYSE,Amex,or Nasdaq during July1963to December2006.RET is the monthly raw return reported in percentage.XRET stands for the monthly excess return,which is the raw return net of the one-month T-bill rate.BETA,ME, and BE/ME are estimated as in Fama and French(1992).BETA is the portfolio beta estimated from the full period using100size and pre-ranking beta portfolios.The market value of equity(ME)is the product of monthly closing price and the number of outstanding shares in June.Book-to-market equity (BE/ME)is the?scal year-end book value of common equity divided by the calendar year-end market value of equity.The idiosyncratic volatility(IVOL)is estimated as follows.In every month,excess daily returns of each individual stock are regressed on the Fama-French three factors:RmRf,SMB,and HML. The(monthly)idiosyncratic volatility of the stock is the product of the standard deviation of the regression residuals and the square root of the number of observations in the month.E(IVOL)is the one-month-ahead expected idiosyncratic volatility estimated by EGARCH models.RET(à2,à7)is the compound gross return from month tà7to tà2.TURN is the average turnover and CVTURN is the coef?cient of variation of turnovers in the past36months.Variables with skewness greater than3.00are reported as the natural logarithm.To avoid giving extreme observations heavy weight in the return regressions and potential data recording errors,the smallest and largest0.5%of the observations in each month for ME,BE/ME,IVOL,E(IVOL),Ret(à2,à7),TURN,and CVTURN are set equal to the next smallest or largest values.Observations with monthly returns greater than300%are deleted.

Variables Mean Std dev.Median Q1Q3Skew N

RET(%) 1.1816.860.15à6.52 6.78 2.352,947,826 XRET(%)0.7116.87à0.27à6.99 6.34 2.352,947,826 Ln(1+RET)(%)à0.1216.090.15à6.74 6.56à0.542,947,826 IVOL14.1713.9110.41 6.3317.41 6.942,946,521 E(IVOL)12.6710.9110.29 6.4615.18 2.382,867,821 BETA 1.220.36 1.170.94 1.460.311,721,356 Ln(ME) 4.29 2.03 4.16 2.82 5.640.342,804,878 Ln(BE/ME)à0.39 1.09à0.35à0.970.200.272,145,253 RET(à2,à7) 1.070.39 1.030.85 1.22 2.902,758,743 Ln(TURN)(%) 1.39 1.09 1.390.67 2.13à0.082,041,658 Ln(CVTURN) 4.150.44 4.14 3.92 4.480.142,038,647

9I also use the maximum log likelihood or the Schwartz information

criterion to select the model of conditional idiosyncratic volatilities.

The?nal results are not sensitive to these alternative selection criteria.

The choice of the maximum number of lags to be three does not drive the

?nal results either.The results also hold for alternative speci?cation such

as two or four.

10It is an empirical question how serious the look-ahead bias would

be.To estimate conditional market volatility,French,Schwert,and

Stambaugh(1987)use the full period data to estimate their GARCH model parameters.They show that assuming time-varying parameters does not change their results.I also?nd the same results by using the full period data to estimate EGARCH model parameters.

11In order to avoid the in?uence of some extremely high returns and possible data recording errors,I exclude333observations that have a monthly return greater than300%.This consists of only0.0001%of the whole sample(which has about three million?rm-month observations).

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3729

The measure of systematic risk,BETA ,is constructed as in Fama and French (1992).In each month,I use the previous 60months of returns to estimate ?rm betas (b )by the market model.Stocks are assigned to 10?10portfolios on the basis of size and b .This procedure rolls every month.I then compute the equal-weighted portfolio returns.For each size-b portfolio,I run the full-period time-series regression of the portfolio return on the current and the prior month’s value-weighted market returns.The portfolio BETA is estimated as the sum of the slopes of these two market returns.The sum is meant to adjust for the effects of non-synchronous trading (Dimson,1979).Finally I allocate the BETA of a size-b portfolio to each stock in the portfolio.These are the BETAs to be used in the cross-sectional regressions of individual stock returns.The mean BETA is 1.22and the median 1.17.

Earlier studies show that ?rm size,the ratio of book-to-market equity,liquidity and its variance,and past returns have effects on cross-sectional returns.12I control for these variables in the following cross-sectional tests.Their summary statistics are also reported in Table 3.Firm size is measured by the market value of equity (ME )—the product of monthly closing price and outstanding share numbers.Following Fama and French (1992),I construct book-to-market equity (BE /ME )as the ?scal year-end book value of common equity divided by the calendar year-end market value of equity.Due to the annual frequency of BE ,this variable is updated yearly.In order to catch the momentum effects,I construct the variable RET (à2,à7),the compound gross return from month t à7to t à2(inclusive)where t represents the month of expected return.The return of t à1is excluded to avoid any spurious association between subsequent month returns caused by thin trading or the bid-ask spread effects.Jegadeesh (1990)shows that thin trading causes returns to exhibit ?rst-order negative serial correlations.Following Chordia,

Subrahmanyam,and Anshuman (2001),liquidity is mea-sured by the average turnover ratio of the previous 36months (TURN )and the coef?cient of variation of these 36monthly turnovers (CVTURN ).

3.2.Cross-sectional simple correlations

I investigate the bivariate relations between these variables.The correlation between return and idiosyn-cratic volatility can be regarded as a univariate test.Variables of ME ,BE /ME ,TURN ,CVTURN are transformed to their natural logarithm because they are signi?cantly skewed.I estimate the simple correlations between these variables in each month and then compute their time-series means.Table 4presents the time-series mean correlation coef?cients.The coef?cients followed by *are signi?cant at the 1%level based on their time-series standard error.The correlation between the monthly return and the contemporaneous idiosyncratic volatility is 0.14and statistically signi?cant at the 1%level (t -stat ?14.09).The correlation between return and the one-month lagged IVOL is,however,à0.016with a t -stat of à2.79(not reported in the table).The contrasting results,in another way,suggest that the lagged IVOL might not be a good proxy for the expected value in the next month.The correlation between return and the conditional idiosyncratic volatility is 0.09and also statistically signi?cant at the 1%level (t -stat ?13.24).The univariate tests therefore imply a positive relation between return and idiosyncratic risk.Consistent with the ?ndings in the literature,the returns are negatively related to size and liquidity,and are positively related to BE /ME and past returns.As shown in Fama and French (1992),the relation between return and BETA is ?at.Conditional idiosyncratic volatilities are negatively related to size and the book-to-market equity ratio,and are positively related to BETA and the two liquidity variables.Small ?rms tend to have higher idiosyncratic volatilities than large ?rms;growth ?rms tend to have higher idiosyncratic volatilities than value ?rms;liquid ?rms tend to have higher idiosyncratic volatilities than illiquid ?rms.The correlation between IVOL and E(IVOL )is a signi?cant 0.46.

Table 4

Cross-sectional simple correlations.

This table presents the time series means of the cross-sectional Pearson correlations.The variables relate to a sample of stocks traded in the NYSE,Amex,or Nasdaq during July 1963to December 2006.Variables are de?ned in Table 3.The correlation coef?cients followed by *are signi?cant at the 1%level based on their time-series standard error.

Ln (1+RET )

IVOL E(IVOL )BETA Ln (ME )Ln (BE /ME )RET (à2,à7)Ln (TURN )Ln (CVTURN )RET

0.98*

0.14*0.09*à0.01à0.01*0.03*0.02*à0.02*à0.00Ln (1+RET )0.05*

0.03*à0.03*0.02*0.04*0.04*à0.03*à0.02*IVOL 0.46*

0.34*à0.39*à0.05*à0.12*0.16*0.31*E(IVOL )0.35*

à0.34*à0.11*à0.04*0.20*0.30*BETA à0.34*

à0.04*à0.03*0.41*0.23*Ln (ME )à0.21*

à0.03*0.04*à0.57*Ln (BE /ME )0.06*

à0.12*0.16*RET (à2,à7)0.00

0.06*Ln (TURN )0.02*

Ln (CVTURN )

12

See,for example,Fama and French (1992)for the effects of size

and book-to-market equity,Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)for the effects of past returns,Amihud and Mendelson (1986),Brennan and Subrahma-nyam (1996),and Amihud (2002)for the effects of liquidity,and Chordia,Subrahmanyam,and Anshuman (2001)for the effects of the variance of liquidity on cross-sectional returns.

F.Fu /Journal of Financial Economics 91(2009)24–37

30

3.3.Month-by-month cross-sectional regressions of individual stocks

I start the empirical analysis by replicating the main results shown by Fama and French(1992),because their paper is highly in?uential in the literature of cross-sectional return studies.By regressing monthly stock returns on beta and various?rm characteristics,Fama and French illustrate that size and BE/ME are two signi?cant determinants for cross-sectional returns and that the relation between return and market beta is?at.Their sample period is from July1963to December1990. My sample extends theirs by16years to December 2006.Following them,I use Fama and MacBeth(1973) regressions to control the cross-correlation in residuals. Speci?cally,for each month in the sample period,I run the following cross-sectional regression:

R it?g0tt

X K

k?1g

kt

X kitt it;i?1;2;...;N t;t?1;2;...;T,

(6)

where R it is the realized return on stock i in month t.X lat are the intended explanatory variables of cross-sectional expected returns such as beta,size,book-to-market ratio, and conditional idiosyncratic volatility.The disturbance term,e it,captures the deviation of the realized return from its expected value.N t denotes the total number of stocks in month t,which can vary from month to month.The maximum month,T,equals522in this study.Eq.(6)is essentially equivalent to Eq.(1).The?nal estimate,^g k,and its variance are given by

^g k ?

1

T

X T

t?1

^g

kt

,(7)

Vare^g kT?

P T

t?1

e^g ktà^g kT2

.(8)

In other words,the average slope is the time-series mean

of the522monthly estimates from July1963to December

2006.The t-statistic is the average slope divided by its

time-series standard error,which is the square root of the

variance of^g k divided by Te

?????????????????????

Vare^g kT=T

p

T.

Following Fama and French(1992),I use size(the

market capitalization,ME)in June to explain the returns of

the following12months and use BE/ME of?scal year t to

explain the returns for the months from July of year t+1to

June of year t+2.The time gap between BE/ME and returns

ensures that the information on BE/ME is available to the

public prior to the returns.The estimation and application

of BETAs also follow Fama and French.Table5presents the

regression results.The?rst model replicates Fama and

French’s three major results.First,the relation between

market beta and average stock return is?at.The average

slope of BETA is not signi?cantly different from zero.

Second,size is negatively related to average returns in the

cross-section.Small?rms on average have higher returns

than large?rms.Third,BE/ME is positively related to

average returns.Value?rms tend to have higher returns

than growth?rms.

Cross-sectional return studies have evolved much since

Fama and French(1992).Liquidity and momentum are

probably the other two most important variables that

have impact on cross-sectional returns.Amihud and

Mendelson(1986)are among the?rst to propose a role

for transaction costs in asset pricing,since rational

investors select assets to maximize their expected return

net of transaction costs.They measure liquidity by the

bid-ask spread and?nd stocks with larger spreads are

expected to have higher returns.The role played by

liquidity is further supported by later studies including

Table5

Fama-MacBeth regressions of stock returns on idiosyncratic volatility and?rm characteristics.

The table presents the time-series averages of the slopes in cross-sectional regressions using the standard Fama and MacBeth(1973)methodology.The t-statistic is the average slope divided by its time-series standard error.The sample period is July1963to December2006.The dependent variable(RET i)is the percentage monthly return.E(IVOL)is the one-month-ahead expected idiosyncratic volatility estimated by an exponential GARCH model.IVOL t is the one-month lagged idiosyncratic volatility.BETA,ME,and BE/ME are estimated as in Fama and French(1992).TURN is the average turnover and CVTURN is the coef?cient of variation of turnovers in the past36months.RET(à2,à7)is the compound gross return from month tà7to tà2.To avoid giving extreme observations heavy weight in the regressions,the smallest and largest0.5%of the explanatory variables(except BETA)are set equal to the next smallest and largest values.This has no effect on inferences.The last column reports the average R-squares of the cross-sectional regressions.

Model BETA Ln(ME)Ln(BE/ME)Ret(à2,à7)Ln(TURN)Ln(CVTURN)E(IVOL t)IVOL tà1IVOL t R2e%T

10.02à0.120.23 3.82

(0.08)(à3.11)(4.97)

20.14à0.170.190.64à0.12à0.44 5.73

(0.93)(à4.52)(4.38)(3.09)(à2.05)(à6.79)

30.11 3.02

(9.05)

40.250.600.13 4.98

(7.28)(12.58)(11.41)

50.190.480.93à0.48à0.730.15 6.89

(5.01)(10.70)(4.74)(à7.34)(à11.82)(13.65)

6à0.210.180.67à0.09à0.39à0.02 5.56 (à5.76)(4.04)(3.36)(à1.24)(à6.48)(à3.73)

70.410.44 1.61à0.55à0.830.3110.42

(14.53)(10.57)(8.55)(à8.54)(à13.59)(20.56)

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3731

Brennan and Subrahmanyam(1996),Datar,Naik,and Radcliffe(1998),Chordia,Subrahmanyam,and Anshuman (2001),Amihud(2002),and Pastor and Stambaugh(2003). Jegadeesh and Titman(1993)show that over an inter-mediate horizon of three to12months,past winners on average continue to outperform past losers,so that there is‘‘momentum’’in stock prices.In other words,past returns tend to predict future returns.The second model in Table5includes the liquidity and momentum variables and con?rms these patterns.TURN is the average share turnover in the past36months,constructed in the same way as in Chordia,Subrahmanyam,and Anshuman(2001). Chordia et al.also?nd that both the level and the volatility of trading activity are related to average returns in the cross-section.Following them,I compute the coef?cient of variation of the previous36months’turn-over(CVTURN).Easley,Hvidkjaer,and O’Hara(2002)adopt the same measures to control for the effects of liquidity.In order to control for the momentum effects,I construct a past return variable,RET(à2,à7),which is the compound gross return from month tà7to month tà2assuming the current month is t.The return of the immediate prior month(tà1)was excluded to avoid any spurious associa-tion between subsequent monthly returns caused by thin trading or bid-ask spread effects(Jegadeesh,1990). Consistent with the previous studies,the coef?cient estimates are positive for the past return variable and negative for the two liquidity variables.

Models3–5in Table5yield striking evidence that expected idiosyncratic volatility is positively related to average returns in the cross-section.Model3is a univariate regression of return on E(IVOL).Model4 controls for size and BE/ME,and Model5in addition controls for past returns and two liquidity variables.The average slopes of E(IVOL)are positive and statistically signi?cant in all three models.The t-statistics are around10. Moreover,the average R-squared increases substantially after including E(IVOL)in the regression.The effects of idiosyncratic risk on expected returns are also economic-ally signi?cant.Since the average slope is over0.10,the average standard deviation of IVOL is about10%,a stock that has an IVOL of one standard deviation higher than the other stock would earn an average return of1%higher in a month.Similarly,as E(IVOL)moves from the?rst quartile to the third quartile,the monthly expected return would increase by more than1%.

In Model6,I include the one-month lagged IVOL as an explanatory variable.The regression results qualitatively con?rm AHXZ’s(2006)?ndings.Monthly returns are negatively related to the lagged IVOL.However,the average slope is onlyà0.02,which casts doubt on how effective investors can make abnormal returns from the negative relation.Shorting stocks whose IVOL are around the third quartile and longing stocks whose IVOL are around the?rst quartile yield a monthly abnormal return of0.2%before accounting for trading costs.Moreover, idiosyncratic volatilities change over time.Trading stra-tegies betting on it need frequent rebalancing and thus are costly.

The last model,Model7,examines the contempora-neous association between the return and the observed idiosyncratic volatility(estimated based on daily returns). The coef?cient of IVOL t is0.31with a t-statistic of20.56. There is a positive and signi?cant association between the realized return and the contemporaneous idiosyncratic risk.From the theory perspective,we are not able to make inferences about expected returns from this regression because of the potential correlation between the un-expected return shockeR tàEeR tTTand the shock on idiosyncratic volatilityeIVOL tàEeIVOL tTT.13The regression results,however,still serve as a reference for comparison. The results of Model5rather than Model6are close to the results of Model7.This provides us some additional con?dence on the positive relation between expected return and idiosyncratic risk.

One result is intriguing.The average slope of size changes sign after including E(IVOL)(or IVOL)in the regression.Controlling for conditional idiosyncratic vola-tility,large?rms have higher average returns than small ?rms.This?nding contrasts to the widely documented ‘‘size effect’’that small?rms have higher average returns than large?rms,but supports one prediction of Merton’s (1987)model that,all else equal,larger?rms have higher expected returns.Merton explicitly points out that the ?ndings of the‘‘size effect’’are due to the omitted controls for other factors such as idiosyncratic risk and investor base(Merton,1987,p.496).My evidence lends direct support to Merton’s prediction.

3.4.Return analysis of portfolios formed on EeIVOLT

The evidence from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions suggests a positive relation between condi-tional idiosyncratic volatility and average stock returns. Next I examine the returns of portfolios formed on the sorting of E(IVOL).This is interesting because the portfo-lio-based approach produces easy-to-interpret returns on a feasible investment strategy.If individual stocks with high E(IVOL)have higher returns than stocks with low E(IVOL),a zero-investment portfolio that is long in high E(IVOL)stocks and short in low E(IVOL)stocks should earn a positive return.

The procedure of the portfolio-based approach is as follows.In each month,I sort E(IVOL)to form10portfolios with an equal number of stocks.The?rst portfolio contains the10%of stocks that are expected to have the lowest idiosyncratic volatilities in the next month and the last portfolio consists of the10%of stocks that are expected to have the highest idiosyncratic volatilities. Table6presents the descriptive statistics for these10 13The covariance between the realized return and the realized

idiosyncratic volatility can be decomposed into four components as follows:

CoveR t;IVOL tT?Cov?EeR tTt t;EeIVOL tTtn t

?Cov?EeR tT;EeIVOL tT tCov?EeR tT;n t

tCov? t;EeIVOL tT tCov? t;n t

The?rst component is of interest.The second and third components are zero by the de?nition of shocks(i.e.,unrelated to the information set at tà1).The last component,the covariance between these two contem-poraneous shocks,is,however,unknown.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–37 32

E(IVOL)-portfolios.The mean E(IVOL)increases from3.19% for the?rst portfolio to36.35%for the last portfolio.The ex post measured idiosyncratic volatility(IVOL)also increases monotonically across these10portfolios.The portfolio consisting of stocks with high E(IVOL)has higher returns than the portfolio consisting of low-E(IVOL)stocks. The value-weighted portfolio returns increase monotoni-cally from0.90%for the lowest-E(IVOL)portfolio to2.65% for the highest-E(IVOL)portfolio.The average monthly return for the zero-investment portfolio is 1.75%.The equal-weighted portfolio returns display a similar pattern and the return spread between the highest and lowest E(IVOL)portfolios is even larger.This evidence con?rms the positive relation between E(IVOL)and individual stock returns.

Next I run the time-series regressions of the value-weighted excess returns on the Fama-French three-factors for each portfolio.The last row of Table6reports the regression intercepts.The alpha is0.03%for the lowest-E(IVOL)portfolio and 1.45%for the highest-E(IVOL) portfolio.A hedging portfolio longing Portfolio10and shorting Portfolio1yields a statistically signi?cant monthly return of1.42%.The Gibbons,Ross,and Shanken (GRS,1989)test statistic has a value of 5.92and thus strongly rejects the null hypothesis that all the intercepts jointly equal zero.This result contrasts sharply with the ?ndings of AHXZ(2006)which are based on the lagged realized volatility and further con?rms that?rms with high expected idiosyncratic volatility have higher ex-pected returns.

3.5.Robustness check

I emphasize the importance to have a quality estimate of E(IVOL)in estimating the relation between idiosyncratic risk and return and use EGARCH models to reach the goal. But theoretically speaking,this goal can also be reached by examining the empirical relation between idiosyncratic volatility and a quality estimate of expected returns.So far I use realized returns as a proxy for expected returns. Though realized returns are an unbiased estimate of expected returns,the estimate quality is rather poor (Elton,1999).Elton therefore encourages‘‘developing better measures of expected return and alternative ways of testing asset pricing theories that do not require using realized returns’’(p.1200).One alternative measure of expected returns is the implied cost of capital(ICC),which is essentially the?rm’s internal rate of return that equates the present value of future dividends to the current stock price.This measure is increasingly used in the accounting and?nance literature.For example,Pastor,Sinha,and Swaminathan(2008)show that the ICC estimated on the basis of earnings forecasts could be a useful proxy for expected stock returns.Based on this estimate,they?nd a positive intertemporal risk and return tradeoff at the market level.

Following Pastor,Sinha,and Swaminathan(2008),I estimate the ICC as a proxy for the expected return of individual stocks.Table7reports the simple correlations between the estimated ICC and idiosyncratic volatility (in Panel A)and the estimates from the Fama-MacBeth regressions by using ICC as the dependent variable (in Panel B).The results are consistent with my earlier ?ndings.Both the correlation coef?cients and the regres-sion slopes of idiosyncratic volatility are positive and statistically signi?cant.In addition,I also tried the expected returns estimated from the Value Line forecasts. These estimates are downloaded from Alon Brav’s Web site.14Brav,Lehavy,and Michaely(2005)use them to test asset pricing models.I again?nd a positive relation between this Value Line forecasted expected return and idiosyncratic volatility.

I check the robustness of the results in many other ways.First,the dependent variable in the Fama-MacBeth regressions is the simple raw return.Simple returns are known to be skewed positively.In addition they have the lower bound ofà100%but no upper bound.This makes the regression results potentially driven by outliers.

Table6

Summary statistics for portfolios formed on conditional idiosyncratic volatility.

Each month?ve portfolios are formed on E(IVOL),the one-month-ahead expected idiosyncratic volatilities of individual stocks.E(IVOL)is estimated by an exponential GARCH model.The?rst portfolio(Low)consists of the10%of stocks with the lowest E(IVOL)and the last portfolio(High)consists of the 10%of stocks with the highest E(IVOL).Portfolios are updated monthly.The?rst two rows present,respectively,the time-series means of the value-weighted and the equal-weighted portfolio returns.Other rows show the pooled means/medians of variables within the particular portfolio.The medians instead of the means of ME and BE/ME are reported due to their substantial skewness.The last row reports the alphas(intercepts)from the time-series regressions of the value-weighted portfolio excess returns on the Fama-French three factors.The sample period is from July1963to December2006.

Variables Portfolios formed on E(IVOL)

Low23456789High

Port.VWRET0.900.960.970.98 1.00 1.02 1.17 1.18 1.28 2.65 Port.EWRET0.540.770.790.800.780.820.850.91 1.41 5.33 E(IVOL) 3.19 5.17 6.527.809.1910.7812.7315.3419.5836.35 IVOL 6.747.808.9810.2911.8013.5015.4617.7220.8127.29 BETA0.90 1.00 1.08 1.16 1.23 1.29 1.36 1.40 1.44 1.46 ME($mil,med)113.03177.16161.38119.0485.8063.0445.6833.8323.7214.19 BE/ME(med)0.900.780.750.740.730.710.680.640.590.52 FF Alphas0.030.01à0.02à0.02à0.05à0.060.040.010.13 1.45

14https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,/$brav/.I thank Alon Brav for making this

data available.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3733

Besides having imposed the upper bound of returns to be 300%for the reported results,I test the robustness by replacing simple returns by log returns(replace R t by ln(1+R t)),which do not have a lower bound and are not skewed,and run the same Fama-MacBeth regressions. The cross-sectional relations between log returns and idiosyncratic volatility remain positive and statistically signi?cant,though become weaker in magnitude.For example,controlling for the variables as in Model5of Table5,the coef?cient estimate is0.09with a t-statistic of 9.94for E(IVOL)and0.17with a t-statistic of13.15for IVOL.

Second,I estimate the test-statistics in the month-by-month cross-sectional regressions by using the general-ized least squares(GLS)method suggested by Litzenber-ger and Ramaswamy(1979).Speci?cally,the GLS estimator,^g k;is the weighted mean of the monthly estimates,where the weights are inversely proportional to the variances of the monthly estimates.15

^g k ?

X T

t?1

Z kt^g kt,(9)

Vare^g kT?

X T

t?1

Z kt Vare^g ktT,(10)

Z kt??Vare^g ktT à1,

X T

t?1

?Vare^g ktT à1.(11)

The results remain qualitatively intact.

Last but not least,my choice of EGARCH models is unlikely to be the exclusive factor that drives the results. The main purpose in using EGARCH models is to improve the estimation of conditional idiosyncratic volatility.Any other models that serve this purpose would deliver similar results as this paper and different results from the na?¨ve model that uses the lagged IVOL as a proxy for E(IVOL).In fact,two contemporaneous studies that use different methods to estimate conditional idiosyncratic volatilities obtain similar results to my study.16

4.The relation between return and lagged idiosyncratic volatility

I have shown that idiosyncratic volatilities of indivi-dual stocks change over time and the lagged IVOL is not an appropriate proxy for the expected IVOL.As a result,the negative relation between return and the one-month lagged IVOL found by AHXZ(2006)should not be used to draw inference on the relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return.Employing the EGARCH models to estimate the expected IVOL,I?nd a signi?cantly positive relation between expected IVOL and expected return. However,AHXZ’s?ndings of the negative relation are still puzzling,though Bali and Cakici(2008)suggest that their results are sensitive to the research methods.In this section I replicate AHXZ’s results by strictly following their methods and then offer an empirical explanation.

My evidence suggests that AHXZ’s?ndings are largely driven by the return reversal of stocks that have high idiosyncratic volatilities.High idiosyncratic volatilities are contemporaneous with high returns,which tend to reverse in the following month.As a result,the returns of high-IVOL stocks are abnormally low in the next month. In addition,the stocks that drive their results are small in size and even in aggregate have a negligible weight

Table7

Cross-sectional relations between the implied cost of capital and idiosyncratic volatility.

Panel A of the table presents the simple correlations between the realized return,the estimated implied cost of capital(ICC),the realized idiosyncratic volatility,and the EGARCH-estimated expected idiosyncratic volatility.The correlation coef?cients followed by*are signi?cant at the1%level based on their time-series standard error.Panel B reports the coef?cient estimates and t-statistics(in parentheses)from the Fama-MacBeth regressions where the dependent variables are the estimated ICC.The estimation of ICC follows Pastor,Sinha,and Swaminathan(2008)and is based on analyst earnings forecasts.Due to the availability of analyst earnings forecasts,the sample period is from January1980to December2006.

ICC IVOL E(IVOL)

Panel A:Simple correlations

RET0.06*0.14*0.07* ICC0.20*0.17* IVOL0.54*

E(IVOL)

MODEL Ln(ME)Ln(BE/ME)Ret(à2,à7)Ln(TURN)Ln(CVTURN)E(IVOL t)IVOl t R2e%T

Panel B:Fama-MacBeth regressions(dependent variable:ICC)

1à0.050.03à0.18à0.01à0.050.0810.09 (à31.94)(6.52)(à24.62)(à1.60)(à7.81)(10.26)

2à0.060.03à0.17à0.02à0.060.0911.18 (à31.42)(6.14)(à23.94)(à3.92)(à7.52)(11.45)

15The Fama-MacBeth regression implicitly assumes equal weights across months.It can be regarded as a speci?c example of GLS in which the variances of monthly estimates are the same.

16Chua,Goh,and Zhang(2007)use an AR(2)model,and Diavato-poulos,Doran,and Peterson(2007)decompose implied volatility from option prices to estimate conditional idiosyncratic volatility.Both studies conclude the positive tradeoff between idiosyncratic risk and expected return.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–37 34

relative to the total market capitalization.The evidence casts doubt on the effectiveness of trading strategies suggested by AHXZ(2006,2008),if transaction costs are seriously accounted for.

I start with replicating the main results in Table6of AHXZ(2006).Their sample period is from July1963to December2000.I extend it by six years to December 2006.My results,reported in Table8,are very similar to theirs.The quintile portfolio of stocks with the highest IVOL has a Jensen’s alpha of1.22%lower than the portfolio of stocks with the lowest IVOL(1.19%in AHXZ,2006). The procedure to get Jensen’s alphas is as follows.In each month,I divide the universe of stocks into quintiles on the basis of their IVOL.Portfolio1(5)is the portfolio of the 20%of stocks with the lowest(highest)IVOL.I compute the value-weighted excess return(VWXRET)in the next month for each portfolio.The weight for each stock is its market capitalization in the previous month.As a result, I have a time-series of value-weighted excess returns for each portfolio.I then run a time-series regression of the VWXRET on the Fama-French three factors.The purpose is to estimate the intercept alpha—the average excess return not explained by these three factors.

Three?ndings are worth mention.First,only two out of the?ve alphas are statistically signi?cant.They are the two alphas for Portfolio4and5whose stocks have relatively high lagged IVOL(hereafter Portfolios4and5 are also called the high-IVOL portfolios).So precisely speaking,the two portfolios of stocks with high lagged idiosyncratic volatilities realize negative abnormal returns but the other three portfolios of stocks with relatively low idiosyncratic volatilities do not realize signi?cant abnor-mal returns.Second,these40%of stocks in the high-IVOL portfolios tend to be small?rms and their total market capitalization is only9%of the whole market.Third,if we read the return numbers literally,the patterns for RET(t), VWXRET(t),and even FF-3F alphas—the metric that AHXZ’s conclusion is based on,are not monotonically increasing or decreasing across the IVOL portfolios.There-fore,AHXZ’s?ndings are completely driven by these small stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities.The question then becomes why these stocks earn low returns in the subsequent month.

In the last three columns of Table8,I present the mean raw return(RET(tà1))and value-weighted excess return (VWXRET(tà1))that are contemporaneous to the IVOL. I?nd that these returns are monotonically increasing in the IVOL portfolios.Moreover,the alphas from the time-series regressions of VWXRET(tà1)on the Fama-French three factors are signi?cantly positive for Portfolios4and5and not different from zero for the other three portfolios.The positive abnormal returns in month tà1and the negative abnormal returns in month t for the high-IVOL portfolios are not likely coincidental.The negative abnormal returns in month t are,at least partly,caused by the reversal of the positive abnormal returns in month tà1.

Next I focus on the40%of‘‘trouble-making’’?rms(i.e., stocks in Portfolios4and5)and examine the impact of return reversal.I divide these?rms into quintiles based on RET(tà1).Table9shows the return dispersions of these?ve portfolios.The mean RET(tà1)increases from à22.67%for the lowest RET(tà1)portfolio to33.78%for the highest RET(tà1)portfolio.Interestingly,the mean raw return in the next month,RET(t),decreases from3.35%to à0.21%monotonically across these?ve RET(tà1)portfo-lios.The portfolio excess return,both the equal-weighted and the value-weighted,show the same pattern.The alphas estimated from the time-series regressions con?rm that the negative abnormal returns in month t concentrate in?rms that have relatively high past returns(RET(tà1)). The evidence suggests that some stocks with high IVOL at month tà1earn positive abnormal returns in the same month and due to the return reversal,realize negative abnormal returns at month t.

The negative correlation of subsequent monthly returns has been noted in the literature for a long time,

Table8

Return dispersion of portfolios sorted by idiosyncratic volatility.

This table illustrates differences in monthly percentage returns of portfolios sorted by idiosyncratic volatilities.In each month,I divide the universe of stocks into quintiles on the basis of their idiosyncratic volatility(IVOL).Portfolio1(5)is the portfolio of stocks with the lowest(highest)IVOL.The idiosyncratic volatility is estimated as follows.In every month,excess daily returns of each individual stock are regressed on the Fama-French three factors:RmRf,SMB,and HML.The(monthly)idiosyncratic volatility of the stock is the product of the standard deviation of the regression residuals and the square root of the number of observations in the month.The month that I form portfolios is indicated as tà1and the subsequent month t.N is the number of?rm-month observations for the pooled sample.The numbers presented in other columns are means with t-statistics in brackets,if any.ME stands for market capitalization.RET is the raw return.VWXRET are the value-weighted excess returns for the portfolio,which are used to compute the FF-3F alphas in the time-series regressions.The sample period is July1963to December2006.

IVOL portfolio N IVOL

(tà1)

ME(tà1)

($mil)

MKT share

(%)

RET

(t)

VWXRET

(t)

FF-3F alpha

(t)

RET

(tà1)

VWXRET

(tà1)

FF-3F alpha

(tà1)

1(Low)574,915 4.301885.0443.00 1.100.520.0740.440.39à0.04

(1.75)(à0.94) 2574,2937.581451.8133.08 1.340.570.0340.550.630.05

(0.76)(1.07) 3574,69411.06653.9314.91 1.370.640.0580.610.76à0.02

(0.83)(à0.13) 4574,70716.17294.70 6.72 1.190.29à0.3530.770.790.26

(à3.60)(2.65)

5(High)574,91532.32100.44 2.29 1.08à0.40à1.146 4.11 1.660.85

(à7.00)(3.14)

5-1à1.2200.89

(à6.45)(3.26)

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3735

e.g.,Jegadeesh (1990).A recent study by Huang,Liu,Rhee,and Zhang (2007)also suggests that the return reversal in monthly returns explains the difference in results between AHXZ (2006)and Bali and Cakici (2008).Controlling for the difference in the past-month returns,there is no negative relation between average returns and the lagged idiosyncratic volatilities.5.Conclusion

For various reasons investors in reality often do not hold perfectly diversi?ed portfolios.Theories assuming under-diversi?cation of investor portfolios,such as Levy (1978)and Merton (1987),predict a positive relation between idiosyncratic risk and expected return.Ang,Hodrick,Xing,and Zhang (2006,2008),however,?nd that monthly stock returns are negatively related to the one-month lagged idiosyncratic volatilities.I show that idiosyncratic volatilities are time-varying and that the one-month lagged value is not a good proxy for the expected value.So AHXZ’s ?ndings should not be used to imply the relation between expected return and idiosyn-cratic risk.I use EGARCH models to estimate the expected idiosyncratic volatilities and ?nd they are positively related to expected returns.The positive relation is both economically and statistically signi?cant and also robust to different testing methods.This evidence supports the theories assuming under-diversi?cation.Stocks that are expected to have high idiosyncratic risk earn high returns in the cross-section.I further show that AHXZ’s ?ndings are driven by a subset of small ?rms with high idiosyn-cratic volatilities.These ?rms have high returns in the month of high idiosyncratic volatility.The high returns reverse in the subsequent month and result in the ?ndings of negative abnormal returns.References

Amihud,Y.,2002.Illiquidity and stock returns:cross-section and time-series effects.Journal of Financial Markets 5,31–56.

Amihud,Y.,Mendelson,H.,1986.Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread.

Journal of Financial Economics 15,223–249.

Ang, A.,Hodrick,R.,Xing,Y.,Zhang,X.,2006.The cross-section of

volatility and expected returns.Journal of Finance 61,259–299.

Ang,A.,Hodrick,R.,Xing,Y.,Zhang,X.,2008.High idiosyncratic volatility

and low returns:International and further U.S.evidence.Journal of Financial Economics,forthcoming.

Bali,T.,Cakici,N.,2008.Idiosyncratic volatility and the cross-section of

expected returns?Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43,29–58.

Bollerslev,T.,1986.Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroske-dasticity.Journal of Econometrics 31,307–328.

Bollerslev,T.,Engle,R.,Wooldridge,J.,1988.A capital asset pricing model

with time-varying covariances.Journal of Political Economy 96,116–131.

Boyer, B.,Mitton,T.,Vorkink,K.,2007.Idiosyncratic volatility and

skewness:time-series relations and the cross-section of expected returns.Unpublished working paper,Brigham Young University.Brav,A.,Lehavy,R.,Michaely,R.,https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,ing expectations to test asset

pricing models.Financial Management 34,31–64.

Brennan,M.,Subrahmanyam,A.,1996.Market microstructure and asset

pricing:on the compensation for illiquidity in stock returns.Journal of Financial Economics 41,441–464.

Brockman,P.,Schutte,M.,2007.Is idiosyncratic volatility priced?The

international evidence.Unpublished working paper,University of Missouri–Columbia.

Campbell,J.,Lettau,M.,Malkiel,B.,Xu,Y.,2001.Have individual stocks

become more volatile?An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk.Journal of Finance 56,1–43.

Chordia,T.,Subrahmanyam, A.,Anshuman,V.,2001.Trading activity

and expected stock returns.Journal of Financial Economics 59,3–32.

Chua,C.,Goh,J.,Zhang,Z.,2007.Idiosyncratic volatility matters for the

cross-section of returns —in more ways than one!Unpublished working paper,Singapore Management University,Singapore.

Datar,V.,Naik,N.,Radcliffe,R.,1998.Liquidity and stock returns:an

alternative test.Journal of Financial Markets 1,203–219.

Diavatopoulos,D.,Doran,J.,Peterson,D.,2007.The information content

in implied idiosyncratic volatility and the cross-section of stock returns:evidence from the option markets.Unpublished working paper,Florida State University.

Dimson,E.,1979.Risk measurement when shares are subject infrequent

trading.Journal of Financial Economics 7,197–226.

Easley, D.,Hvidkjaer,S.,O’Hara,M.,2002.Is information risk a

determinant of asset returns?Journal of Finance 57,2185–2221.Eiling,E.,2006.Can nontradable assets explain the apparent premium

for idiosyncratic risk?The case of industry-speci?c human capital.Unpublished working paper,Tilburg University,Netherlands.

Engle,R.,1982.Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity with

estimates of the variance of United Kingdom in?ation.Econometrica 50,987–1007.

Engle,R.,Mustafa,C.,1992.Implied ARCH models from options prices.

Journal of Econometrics 52,289–311.

Engle,R.,Ng,V.,1993.Time-varying volatility and the dynamic behavior

of the term structure.Journal of Money,Credit and Banking 25,336–349.

Table 9

Return dispersion of high-IVOL stocks sorted by the one-month lagged return.

This table examines the impact of return reversal on the high-IVOL stocks.At month t à1,I identify 40%of stocks that have the highest idiosyncratic volatilities and divide them into quintiles on the basis of their contemporaneous returns.Portfolio 1(5)is the portfolio of stocks with the lowest (highest)RET(t à1).RET is the raw monthly percentage return.VWXRET (EWXRET)are the time-series mean value-weighted (equal-weighted)excess returns (R pt àr ft )for the portfolio,which are used to compute the FF-3F alphas in the time-series regressions.The sample period is July 1963to December 2006.Portfolio sorted by RET(t à1)N

RET(t à1)

RET(t )

EWXRET(t )

VWXRET(t )

IVOL(t )

ME(t à1)($mil)FF-3F alpha (EWXRET(t ))FF-3alpha (VWXRET(t ))1(Low)232,405à22.67 3.35 2.840.5628.10155.23 1.77à0.33(6.55)(à1.52)2223,492à8.39 1.170.930.3521.63193.63à0.07à0.41(à0.46)(à2.67)3228,8080.000.900.670.0920.32193.69à0.48à0.57(à3.62)(à4.54)4233,5119.150.450.02à0.0619.35228.15à0.83à0.70(à7.23)(à6.02)5(High)

231,406

33.78

à0.21

à0.62

à0.10

21.15

216.79

à1.40à0.69(à9.49)

(à5.66)

F.Fu /Journal of Financial Economics 91(2009)24–37

36

Elton,E.,1999.Expected return,realized return,and asset pricing tests.

Journal of Finance54,1199–1220.

Fama,E.,French,K.,1992.The cross-section of expected stock returns.

Journal of Finance48,427–465.

Fama,E.,French,K.,https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7f9646345.html,mon risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds.Journal of Financial Economics33,3–56.

Fama, E.,French,K.,1996.Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies.Journal of Finance52,55–84.

Fama,E.,MacBeth,J.,1973.Risk,return and equilibrium:empirical tests.

Journal of Political Economy81,607–636.

French,K.,Schwert,G.,Stambaugh,R.,1987.Expected stock returns and volatility.Journal of Financial Economics19,3–29.

Fuller,W.,1996.Introduction to Statistical Time Series.Wiley,New York. Gibbons,M.,Ross,S.,Shanken,J.,1989.A test of the ef?ciency of a given portfolio.Econometrica57,1121–1152.

Goetzmann,W.,Kumar, A.,2004.Why do individual investors hold under-diversi?ed portfolios?Unpublished working paper,Yale University.

Harvey, C.,Siddique, A.,2000.Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests.Journal of Finance55,1263–1295.

Huang,W.,Liu,Q.,Rhee,G.,Zhang,L.,2007.Another look at idiosyncratic risk and expected returns.Unpublished working paper,University of Hawaii at Manoa.

Jegadeesh,N.,1990.Evidence of predictable behavior of security returns.

Journal of Finance45,881–898.

Jegadeesh,N.,Titman,S.,1993.Returns to buying winners and selling losers:implications for stock market ef?ciency.Journal of Finance 48,65–92.Jiang G.,Xu,D.,Yao,T.,2006.The information content of idiosyncratic volatility.Unpublished working paper,University of Arizona. Levy,H.,1978.Equilibrium in an imperfect market:a constraint on the number of securities in the portfolio.American Economic Review68, 643–658.

Litzenberger,R.,Ramaswamy,K.,1979.The effect of personal taxes and dividends on capital asset prices:theory and empirical evidence.

Journal of Financial Economics7,163–195.

Malkiel, B.,Xu,Y.,2002.Idiosyncratic risk and security returns.

Unpublished working paper,University of Texas at Dallas.

Merton,R.,1987.A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information.Journal of Finance42,483–510.

Nelson,D.,1991.Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns:a new approach.Econometrica59,347–370.

Pagan,A.,Schwert,G.,1990.Alternative models for conditional stock volatility.Journal of Econometrics45,267–290.

Pastor,L.,Stambaugh,R.,2003.Liquidity risk and expected stock returns.

Journal of Political Economy111,642–685.

Pastor,L.,Sinha,M.,Swaminathan,B.,2008.Estimating the intertemporal risk-return tradeoff using the implied cost of capital.Journal of Finance,forthcoming.

Pontiff,J.,2006.Costly arbitrage and the myth of idiosyncratic risk.

Journal of Accounting and Economics42,35–52.

Schwert,G.,1989.Why does stock market volatility change over time?

Journal of Finance44,1115–1153.

Spiegel,M.,Wang,X.,2006.Cross-sectional variation in stock returns: liquidity and idiosyncratic risk.Unpublished working paper,Yale University.

F.Fu/Journal of Financial Economics91(2009)24–3737

相关文档