文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › 2004 Chow..Money,price level and output in the Chinese Macro Economy

2004 Chow..Money,price level and output in the Chinese Macro Economy

Money, Price Level and Output in the Chinese Macro Economy

Gregory C Chow*

Princeton University

gchow@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/8a18450557.html,

Yan Shen

Peking University

yshen@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/8a18450557.html,

November, 2004

Abstract

Following a monetary history of the Chinese macro-economy, an error correction model to explain inflation from 1954 to 2002 is presented that passes the Chow test of parameter stability

in spite of institutional changes. A VAR explaining the logs of price level, output and money supply yields impulse responses that support the Friedman proposition that output reacts to money shocks first but the effect is short-lived and prices react later but the effect lasts longer. A similar VAR using US data shows the same pattern of impulse responses as the Chinese case, confirming the universality of the Friedman proposition as stated in Bernanke (2003).

* I would like to acknowledge with thanks helpful comments from Milton Friedman, Chris Sims and seminar participants at Princeton University and financial support from the Center for Economic Policy Studies at Princeton University in conducting this research.

I. Introduction

This paper presents an abridged history of China’s macroeconomy from the early 1950s to 2004. It is abridged because only three macroeconomic variables, money stock M, real output Y and the price level P are analyzed. The basic hypothesis concerning the co-movements of these three variables is due to the work of Milton Friedman (1994). A major proposition guiding our work is that when money supply increases, whatever the cause, real output will first increase before the price level increases but real output will die down more rapidly than prices. This proposition will be used to explain the changes in the price level and output in relation to the changes in money stock in China’s macroeconomic history from the 1950s to 2004. This is done in section II.

In section III we will explain the price level and inflation statistically by first estimating a linear regression of log P on log(M/P). If this regression is interpreted as a long-run equilibrium relation, or a cointegrating relation, between log P, and log (M/Y), the residuals can be interpreted as deviations from equilibrium or errors in the explanation of log P, to be denoted by u. To explain inflation as measured by ?log P, we use as explanatory variables its own lagged value, ?log(M/Y) and u(t-1). The coefficient of u(t-1) is expected to be negative because a value of log P above equilibrium in the last period will tend to dampen price increase in the current period in this error-correction equation to explain inflation. This section updates the work of Chow (1987) and follows the methodology of Engle and Granger (1987). One interesting result is that the parameters of this error-correction equation explaining inflation are temporally stable from 1954 to 2002 as confirmed by the Chow (1960) test using 1979, the year economic reform started, as the break point.

We estimate in section IV a VAR to explain the changes in the three variables, log M, log P and log Y, denoted by the vector x. The VAR is a vector regression of ?x(t) on x(t-1) and ?x(t-1). By the maximum likelihood method of Johansen (1991), the coefficient matrix of x(t-1) is found to have rank one, to be written as ab’. The vector b’x(t-1) corresponds to the regression of log P on log(M/Y) in section III, and turns out to be similar numerically. Using this VAR we compute the impulse responses of log P and log Y to unexpected changes in M2. The dynamic effects are found to be consistent with the major propositions of Milton Friedman stated above on the effects of money supply on price and output, and as recently summarized in Bernanke (2003).

Section V compares the impulse responses estimated by using US and Chinese data with M1 replacing M2, and finds that the general patterns are quite similar in spite of the institutional differences between these two countries. Section VI concludes.

It is worthwhile in the introduction to state the possible contribution of this paper and the position that we take to avoid possible misunderstanding. On our presentation of monetary history although the facts are well-known our interpretation is perhaps original and provides a background for the econometric analysis to follow. On the reliability of Chinese data, we believe that the data selected are reliable for econometric analysis as illustrated by examples presented in Chow (2002) and elsewhere. We ask a skeptical reader to keep and open mind and see what the analysis of this paper will show. Concerning the possible effect of institutional changes after 1978, it is our purpose to find out whether the effects of money on prices and output and whether the relation between inflation and the ratio of money supply and output remained the same after economic reform. The fact that China had a planned economy before 1979 does not rule out the possibility that the mechanism explaining inflation remains valid. Just witness the inflation of over 16 percent in 1961 which could be explained by the large reduction in output and a substantial increase in money supply. When the first author started using the error-correction model to explain inflation in 1985, data up to only 1984 were available and were used to estimate an equation that was capable of predicting in 1985 (before the fact) – see Chow (1987) for a revised version of this study.

Although the VAR model used is crude, it helps to summarize the statistical properties of the data and sheds light on our main question as to whether the Friedman empirical proposition is valid. This paper should not be viewed as a contribution to testing a macroeconomic theory based on sound micro foundations, but only as a test of an empirical proposition proposed by Friedman. The empirical validity of the Friedman proposition as stressed by Bernankee (2003) for the Chinese economy appears to us as an important question to study. When we estimate a similar VAR using US data we do not claim that this is a contribution to macro-econometric studies of the US. Our purpose is to find out whether the empirical validity of the Friedman proposition uncovered from the Chinese data is also found using similar US data. If the answer is positive, we can conclude that the Friedman proposition is empirically valid for both China and the US even when the conclusion is based on crude VAR models that may ignore many important elements of

both economies. We will test the robustness of the impulse responses in the US case by adding interest rate as an additional variable.

II. A Brief Monetary History of the Chinese Macro-economy

In this section we provide a brief explanation of the important movements of price and output in response to changes in money supply where money supply itself can be the result of other factors. This is a simplified economic history but it can be interesting to the extent that money supply changes can be explained and the resulting movements in price and output are consistent with Friedman’s proposition as stated at the beginning of this paper. We start with an explanation of the large price changes, and then explain the large output changes.

Table 1 provides five sets of data from 1954 to 2002: General retail price index P at the end of the year (column 2), the inflation rate measured by 100 times P(t)/P(t-1) (column 3), real GDP index Y (column 4), M2 at the end of the year in 100 million yuan (column 5) and M1 at the end of the year (column 6).

Table 1 Price Level of China and its Determinants

Year General retail

price index P t/P t-1

x100

GDP index M2 M1

1952 0.8227 99.6

22 74.50314 64.6 1953 0.8506 103.4

25.1 82.00875 79.0 1954 0.8705 102.3

26.6 90.20963 87.4 1955 0.8793 101.0

28.3 94.85521 89.9 1956 0.8793 100.0

32.3 132.3043 120.0 1957 0.8926 101.5

33.7 139.0515 133.9 1958 0.8947 100.2

41.2 194.0242 213.5 1959 0.9028 100.9

44.6 226.401 257.4 1960 0.9308 103.1

43.9 256.6131 289.3 1961 1.082 116.2 30.9 286.1142 359.2 1962 1.1229 103.8

28.9 233.48 353.5 1963 1.0567 94.1

32 214.0444 365.6 1964 1.0177 96.3

37.2 214.5185 352.4 1965 0.9904 97.3

43.5 246.5319 399.6 1966 0.9875 99.7

50.9 285.2925 454.5 1967 0.9801 99.3

44.5 309.5001 499.1 1968 0.9809 100.1

44.2 335.6512 520.6 1969 0.9698 98.9

52.7 336.8679 505.6

65 320.8612 506.6

1970 0.9676 99.8

69.5 357.9469 553.8

1971 0.9603 99.2

71.5 404.8609 586.7

1972 0.9581 99.8

77.5 454.3348 681.4

1973 0.9639 100.6

78.3 494.3595 769.2

1974 0.9691 100.5

84.9 525.0772 845.4

1975 0.9706 100.2

82.6 573.4608 900.6

1976 0.9735 100.3

89 595.6617 905.6

1977 0.9934 102.0

1978 1.000 100.7 100 668.1896 954.7

1979 1.02 102.0 107.6 867.0332 1208.1

1980 1.081 106.0 116 1178.303 1486.2

1981 1.107 102.4 122.1 1453.783 1707.0

1982 1.128 101.9 133.1 1761.087 1972.9

1983 1.145 101.5 147.6 2247.387 2291.5

170 3171.021 3233.0 1984 1.177 102.8

192.9 4188.024 3450.1 1985 1.281 108.8

210 5460.866 4393.8 1986 1.358 106.0

234.3 7154.482 5173.1 1987 1.457 107.3

260.7 9378.91 6376.4 1988 1.727 118.5

1989 2.034 117.8

271.3 11836.63 6804.6

281.7 15293.4

6950.7 1990 2.077 102.1

8633.3

307.6 19349.9 1991 2.137 102.9

11731.5 1992 2.252 105.4

351.4 25402.2

398.8 34879.8

16280.4 1993 2.549 113.2

20540.7

449.3 46923.5 1994 3.102 121.7

496.5 60705.5

23987.1 1995 3.561 114.8

28514.8

544.1 76094.9 1996 3.778 106.1

34826.3

592 90995.3 1997 3.808 100.8

38953.7

638.5 104498.5 1998 3.709 97.4

45837.3 1999 3.598 97.0

684.1 119897.9

738.8 134610.3

53147.2 2000 3.544 98.5

59871.6

794.2 158301.9 2001 3.516 99.2

857.4 185007

70881.8 2002 3.47 98.7

Data Sources: China Statistical Yearbook (2003), for general retail price index, 1978 - 2002 (pp.313), GDP index, 1978 – 2002 (pp. 58), M1 and M2, 1990 – 2002 (pp. 704). The 1952 – 1977 data for the indices are also from earlier years of China Statistical Yearbook but directly taken from Chow (2002), page 120. The pre-1990 M1 is constructed as currency in circulation plus demand deposits. The pre-1990 M2 is approximated as linking currency plus savings deposits data with the official M2 series, where the linking factor is 1.58 (official M2 of 1990) / (currency + savings deposits in 1990).

To explain inflation we consider a weak form of the quantity theory of money because the functional form of the quantity equation Mv=PY may not be correct empirically. The weak form states that, with Y held constant, P tends to increase as M increases; with M constant, P tends to

increase as Y decreases, and P constant, Y tends to increase as M increases. The quantity theory as specified by the particular functional form of the quantity equation may not be empirically valid even in the long run for various reasons. First, interest rate affects v and may not be constant in the long run. Second, interpreted as a demand for money equation (M/P) = Y/v, it implies an income elasticity of unity which may be empirically incorrect. We take from the quantity theory not the exact quantity equation but a weaker proposition as stated above. To explain P we first find out whether the variable M has changed if the relative change in M is much larger than the change in Y. We also examine whether Y has changed and if so it is expected to have a negative effect on P. These basic ideas are used to interpret the major changes in prices and output in China. The explanation is given verbally and informally in this section, and more formally in statistical terms in the next section.

We first examine the major changes in the price index and its relation to changes in M and possibly to Y, the latter asserting a negative effect. The data of Table 1 reveals that all episodes of inflation were associated with substantial increase in the ratio M/Y. In 1961 the price index increased by 16.1 percent while money stock (measured by M2 in this exposition but M1 will do as well) increased from 226.4 in 1959 to 286.1 in 1961, or by 26.4 percent and the real output index decreased dramatically from 43.9 in 1960 to 30.9 in 1961. The dramatic decline in output was a result of the economic failure of the Great Leap Forward Movement that had started in 1958.

In the era of economic reform after 1978 there have been episodes of inflation in 1985, 1988, and 1993-5. Money stock increased from 2247.4 at the end of 1983 to 4188.0 at the end of 1985, or by 86.3 percent in these two years, more in percentage terms than for any previous two years. The inflation rate in 1985 was 8.8 percent. The reason for the rapid increase in money stock was the banking reform policy introduced in 1982-3 to allow the banks more autonomy to extend credits, perhaps similar to the autonomy introduced for state-owned enterprises in the reform process. From the end of 1986 to the end of 1988 money stock increased from 5460.9 to 9378.9 or by 71.7 percent in these two years. The government did not slow down the fairly rapid increase in money supply perhaps because it did not understand the mechanism of inflation as we specify in section III. The inflation rate in 1988 was 18.5 percent. The reason for this inflation rate to be higher than the rate in 1985 is the delayed effects of the substantial increases in money supply for several

years prior to 1988 while the percentage increases in the years prior to 1983 were much smaller. It has been observed that inflation in 1988, together with government corruption, were the two major causes of discontent among the population and indirectly of the tragic Tiananmen Incident on June 4, 1989.

From the end of 1991 to the end of 1996 money stock increased from 19349.9 to 76094.9 or by a factor of 3.93 in 5 years. The inflation rates in 1993, 1994 and 1995 were 13.2, 21.7 and 14.8 percent respectively. The large increases in money stock in these years were the result of Deng Xiaoping’s Southern Expedition in February 1992 in which he set forth a policy of further reform and opening and urged rapid development of the economy. Banks received the green light to expand credit for investment projects. It was Zhu Rongji as Governor of the People’s Bank or Central Bank and later as Vice Premier who managed to stop the rapid increase in money supply after 1996 (as seen in Table 1). He did so mainly by the administrative means of assigning credit quotas to the People’s Banks of different provinces and succeeded in stopping inflation. A provincial People’s bank’s president would lose his job if the credit quota were exceeded.

We next turn briefly to the effects on output associated with the large increases in money supply in the above episodes. Since the average rate of annual growth of real output was about 9.5 percent from 1979 to 1998, any increase much above that average can be considered large. Output increased by 170/147.6 or 15.2 percent in1984 and by 192.9/170 or 13.5 percent in 1985 when money supply increased very rapidly in 1983-4. It increased by 260.7/234.3 or 11.3 percent in 1988, and by 449.3/398.8 or 12.7 percent in 1994. This is a part of the history of China’s economic fluctuations as measured by changes in total output.

The data in Table 1 terminate in 2002, but macroeconomic developments up to the second quarter of 2004 are also consistent with the Friedman proposition that increase in money supply first leads to increase in output and then to increase in prices. Money supply increased rapidly in 2002-3 mainly as a result of the large inflow of foreign exchanges acquired through large trade surplus and large inflow of foreign investment. The acquired foreign exchange was converted into high power money in the banks. This led to rapid expansion of money and credit and to increases in investment and output in 2003. The annual rate of increase in M2 was about 13 percent in January 2002, rose to over 18 percent at the end of 2002 and to over 21 percent in mid-2003, and was

reduced to about 18 percent in the beginning of 2004. China’s real GDP increased at a 9.1 percent rate in 2003 and a 9.8 percent rate in the first quarter of 2004 as compared with 8.0 percent in 2002 (see Table 1). Signs of inflation began to show in the last quarter of 2003, with the rate of inflation rising to 3.8 percent annually in April 2004 (the highest rate in seven years).

In presenting this abridged history of the Chinese macroeconomy we have to be aware of the possible inaccuracy of the Chinese official data on which our exposition is based. Support for the usefulness and reliability of most official Chinese data has been given in Chow (1985; 2002, pp. 90-91, 152-3; 2004, pp. 59-63). The accuracy of the data given in Table 1 can be inferred partly by using them to interpret economic reality based on confirmed economic hypotheses. The above discussion of the effect of money on prices and output is an example, while other examples can be found in Chow (2002). The accuracy of economic data and the validity of well accepted economic hypotheses in explaining the data help to reinforce each other. The fact that official output statistics in Table 1 show a large reduction of real output in 1961 from 43.9 to 30.9 suggests that official statisticians are willing to report large economic failures of China. We hope that the reader will be able to form a better judgment on the accuracy of these data after reading the remainder of this paper.

Nevertheless Young (2003) has raised questions on the accuracy of Chinese output data. His main point is that if we deflate output in money terms by its implicit deflator to obtain real output, the estimate of increase in real output is too large if the deflator underestimates the true inflation rate. By replacing the output deflator by another official price index, such as the retail price index shown in his Table 3 for deflating output of the Secondary (industrial) sector, we will get a smaller rate of growth of real output. The most dramatic difference between the two results is found in Young (2003, p. 1233) for the growth of GDP in 1989 when his alternative estimate shows a negative 5 percent and the official estimate shows a positive 4 percent (from Table 1, 271.3/260.7 =1.041). The alternative estimate is grossly in error. First, the retail price index in 1989 was abnormally high according to the explanation given in section III below (see Figures 2 and 3 and Table 2 for the two large positive residuals in 1988 and 1989 and the verbal explanation following Table 2). Second, China Statistical Yearbook 1990 (Tables 10-29 and 10-30) provides data on outputs in physical units of individual industrial products and most of them show an increase in 1989 as compared with 1988. Third, China’s real GDP was growing at 11.3 percent in

1988 and a reduction to the official rate of 4.1 percent in 1989 was a very large reduction. Peaceful demonstrations did not start until April and the Tiananmen Incident occurred on June 4, 1989. We can reasonably assume that for the first six months of 1989, real GDP was increasing at least at 7 percent annually as compared with 11.3 percent the year before. To get a negative growth of -5 percent for the entire year would require an annual rate of decline in output of about -17 percent (3.5 in the first half and -8.5 in the second half) in the second half of 1989, which is highly unlikely. Much of the revision of output growth given in Young (2003) is due to this very large difference of -9 percent in one year.

III. An error-correction model to explain inflation in China

This section updates the work of Chow (1987) to explain the change in log P by its lagged value, the change in log(M/Y) and an error-correction term, where M denotes money supply and Y denotes real output. M2 is used because our simple model fails to include the rate of interest which may affect the demand for M1 more than it affects M2 as an increase in the interest rate would tend to reduce the demand for M1 relative to the interest yielding deposits in the remainder of M2. Results from using M1 for money stock will be reported in section IV for comparison with corresponding results for the United States.

After pointing out in the previous section the relation between changes in the price level and associated changes in money stock or real output in the major inflation episodes (real output being less volatile than the money stock except for the year 1961) we examine the statistical relation between log P and log (M/Y). Figure 1 plots log(P) against log(M2/Y) over the entire sample period. Overall, the plot suggests that in the long run, the relation between log(P) and log(M2/Y) is approximately linear.

Figure 1 Plotting log(P) against log(M2/Y)

The long run relation between log(P) and log(M2/Y) is then estimated by regressing log(P) on log(M2/Y) and a constant:

),/2log(3738.07127.0)log()

0102.0()

031.0(Y M P +?= Adjusted 9639.02=R .

Following Chow (1987; 2002, p. 124), the lagged value of the residual 1t u ? of the above regression is used as an independent variable representing the error correction term in estimating the equation that explains the inflation rate log()P ?:

1)

055.0(1)

052.0(1)

108.0()

0429.0()

0065.0(169.0))/2(log(031.0)(log 55.0)/2(log 1603.00009.0)log(???????+?+?=?u Y M P Y M P

Adjusted 6274

.02=R . The residuals of the above model are plotted in Figure 2 to examine how well this model explains the data:

Figure 2 The Residual Plot for Model 1 (including 1log((/))M Y ??

)

As ))/log((1??Y M is not significant, it is omitted in the following regression:

,1575.0)(log 525.0)/2(log 155.000017.0)log(1)

0512.0(1)

0924.0()

042.0()

006.0(????+?+?=?u P Y M P Adjusted 6328.02=R .

Figure 3 plots its residuals and Table 2 presents the data on the residuals from the two models:

Figure 3 Residuals Plot for Model 2 (without 1log((/))M Y ??

Table 2 Residuals for Model 1 and Model 2

Year Model 1

Model 2

Year

Model 1 Model 2

1954 0.0147977 0.0170414 1979 -0.0144812 -0.0121256 1955 0.0190982 0.0183888 1980 0.0066371 0.0044539 1956 -0.0167619 -0.0154329 1981 -0.0408543 -0.0431887 1957 0.0286838 0.0230097 1982 -0.0263746 -0.027474 1958 -0.0162445 -0.0149646 1983 -0.0381648 -0.0373604 1959 0.0025254 -0.0002004 1984 -0.03873 -0.038349 1960 0.0047668 0.0045939 1985 0.0132897 0.0124603 1961 0.0598597 0.060335 1986 -0.0463408 -0.0438876 1962 -0.018769 -0.0270627 1987 -0.0171425 -0.0164363 1963 -0.0483036 -0.043342 1988 0.0764033 0.0780104 1964 0.0230726 0.0265138 1989 0.0282354 0.0319061 1965 0.0038139 0.0072676 1990 -0.0986465 -0.0970142 1966 0.0217711 0.021822 1991 -0.009471 -0.0130061 1967 -0.0323494 -0.0304916 1992 0.0048834 0.0040563 1968 -0.0088929 -0.0138018 1993 0.0545428 0.0550307 1969 0.006617 0.0048992 1994 0.0996994 0.100275 1970 0.0373395 0.0421248 1995 0.0256512 0.0273882 1971

-0.0079749 0.0002567 1996

-0.0041078 -0.0047449

1972 -0.0028541 -0.0034836 1997 -0.0041265 -0.0069718

1973 0.0073827 0.0054422 1998 -0.0105428 -0.0137002

1974 -0.007269 -0.0067967 1999 -0.00578 -0.008478

1975 0.0018947 0.0008898 2000 0.0071973 0.0046898

1976 -0.0177193 -0.0153195 2001 -0.008238 -0.0087092

1977 0.0205188 0.0184406 2002 -0.0212666 -0.0226344

1978 -0.0072758 -0.0043201

The last error correction equation, with the lagged change in log (M2/Y) omitted, explains the data well. All coefficients have the right sign, including the negative sign for the lagged error or residual in the cointegrating equation estimated by least squares. However, we have found very large residuals in the years 1961, 1988 and 1993-4. The 1961 residual was associated with the Great Leap, with a large increase in money supply and a large reduction in real output in 1961 the effect of which is not sufficiently captured by our equation. The 1988 residual can be attributed to the government announcement, for the sake of controlling inflation at the time, that after December 1988 no price increase was to be allowed. Such an announcement had the effect of inducing retailers to raise their prices in the fall of 1988 before the December deadline. The 1993-94 residuals can be attributed to the effect of Deng Xiaoping's Southern Expedition further opening speech in 1992 which was followed by the Chinese people and government officials seizing the opportunity to follow Deng’s urge to expand investments, leading to inflationary pressure as demand for investment goods increased, more so than our equation can explain. In general the equation shows that the theory explains the data well and that the residuals can be used to interpret historical events. From 1997 to 2002 China experienced deflation as shown by the price index in Table 1 while the residuals of our error-correction equation presented in Table 2 are small, showing that our model explains successfully price decreases as well as price increases.

It would be of interest to find out whether the parameters of our error-correction equation changed after 1979, the year economic reform started to change a planned economy towards a market-oriented economy. We all agree that changes in Chinese economic institutions took place after 1979. However such changes in economic institutions need not change the relation between changes in log price and the determinants given by our equation. The Chow test for testing the null hypothesis of stability of all parameters in our error-correction equation yields an F(4,41) statistic of only 0.78, as compared with the 5 percent critical level of 2.60 and the one percent critical level of 3.51. Hence the null hypothesis of parameter stability is easily accepted. The

result of the stability test further supports the validity of our error-correction model in explaining inflation in China.

IV. A VAR Model with Cointegration

In this section we report on a VAR explaining the vector ?x composed of ?log (P), ?log (M2) and ?log (Y) by x(t-1) and ?x(t-1). The coefficient matrix of x(t-1) is written as ab’ where b’ is the

transpose of the cointegrating vector. The cointegrating equation b’x was estimated in section III by regressing log (P) on log (M2/Y), as suggested by Engle and Granger (1987) under our assumption that the coefficients of log (M2) and log(Y) are opposite in sign and equal in magnitude. We first apply the method of Johansen (1991) to find the rank of the coefficient matrix of x(t-1). Table 3 reports the trace statistics for the number of cointegrating relations:

Table 3 Johansen Cointegration Test Series: LOG(P) LOG(Y) LOG(M2)

Trace Statistic

5 Percent 1 Percent Hypothesized Eigenvalue Critical Value Critical Value No. of CE(s)

0.27 35.34 34.91 41.07 None * 0.26 19.91 19.96 24.60 At most 1 0.10

5.16

9.24

12.97

At most 2

* Denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5%(1%) significance level. Critical values are taken from Enders (2003, p. 403), the panel of critical value for the case with a constant in the cointegrating vector.

The result supports using one cointegrating relation among log(P), log( Y) and log(M2). Hence the rank of the coefficient matrix for the lagged dependent variables is one, and the normalized cointegrating equation is 1'?t x b =3498.0)2log(5.0)log(6509.0)log(111+?+???t t t M y P . Figure 4 compares this cointegrating equation with the residuals 1?t u from regressing log(P) on log(M2/Y). It shows that the cointegrating equation and the vector u(t-1) estimated in section 1 exhibit similar behavior.

Figure 4 Plotting the Long-run Relation and Residuals from the OLS Regression

As the Johansen Cointegration Test shows one cointegrating relation, we estimate a vector error-correction VAR assuming one cointegrating relation, numbers in brackets are standard deviations : ?????????????+?????????????????

?????????+??

???

?

?????????=?????????????????)02.0()02.0()009.0(111)14.0()17.0()28.0()13.0()16.0()26.0()05.0()07.0()11.0(1)15.0()14.0()06.0(045.0064.0015.0)2log()log()log(43.053.022.017.046.006.011.0137.054.0'07.024.0163.0)2log()log()log(t t t t t t t M y P x b M y P

We are interested in finding out how the price level and real output respond to monetary shocks in the Chinese economy. According to Friedman (1994, p.48), because of price rigidity, the effects of monetary shock will first show up for log output over two to three quarters. Such effects tend to dissipate over time. "The effect on prices, like that on income and output, is distributed over time, but it comes some twelve to eighteen months later, so that the total delay between a change in monetary growth and a change in the rate of inflation averages something like two years". This proposition is confirmed by the studies on US data (Sims (1980), Bernanke and Mihov (1998)) and empirical studies for “virtually all countries” (Bernanke (2003)). However, whether the Chinese data exhibit a similar pattern has not been thoroughly studied. This question is of particular interest since some researchers argue that the institutional differences between the Chinese economy and those of the highly developed economies could make a fundamental difference in explaining the relation between money, price and output (e.g., Peebles (1992)).

We quantify the dynamic effects of monetary shocks on real output and prices by calculating the impulse responses based on the VAR model presented in section 2. Figure 5 plots the impulse responses of log (Y) and log(P) to shocks to M2 over 20 years, respectively. The ordering of these three variables in calculating the impulse responses are P, M, and Y. With this ordering the immediate response of lnP is zero by construction to agree with the prior assumption. Effects of changing the ordering to M, Y, P will be reported in Section V. The result suggests that the dynamic relations between real output, money and price conform Friedman’s proposition. In the first year after the expansionary monetary shock, most of the impacts are on real output (the lower panel of figure 5). In the second year, the impact on real output die down quickly, but reaches its maximum for price (the upper panel of Figure 5). The impacts on price then die out over a long horizon.

Figure 5 Impulse Responses for Chinese M2 Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Response of DLNP to DLNM23

0.020

0.015

0.010

0.005

0.000

-0.005

2468101214161820

Response of DLNY to DLNM23

0.06

0.04

0.02

0.00

-0.02

-0.04

2468101214161820

V. Comparing the Impulse Responses from US data and Chinese Data

While the impulse response functions for the Chinese data reported in section IV are consistent with Friedman’s predictions, the VAR specification is not the same as in empirical studies for other countries. To compare our results with results based on US data, we use the same VAR specification for the US as given in section IV.

The US annual data is extracted from the dataset prepared for the Fair model provided by Ray Fair in the website https://www.wendangku.net/doc/8a18450557.html,/. As only M1 is available in that dataset and it is of interest to reexamine the Chinese impulse responses based on M1 as well, we estimate the VAR model using US M1, real GDP and GDP deflator over the sample period 1966 – 2002 and record the impulse responses of US real output and price level to shocks on US M1 in Figure 6. To make the impulse responses comparable we use Chinese M1 and report the impulse responses in Figure 7.

Figure 6 shows that the general patterns of the responses of real output and price level to monetary shocks agree with Friedman’s proposition. The response of output occurs sooner than the response of price but dies down quickly. The response of price peaks at two to three years and dies down much more gradually. Furthermore, by examining the output and price responses using M1 instead of M2, and after changing the ordering of the variables to M, Y, P instead of P, M, Y, we will find that the impulse responses calculated from the US data (Figures 8, 9 and 12) and from the Chinese data (Figures 7, 10 and 11) to be quite similar and to follow the pattern just described.

Figure 6 Impulse Responses of Real Output and Price to US M1 shocks

Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Response of DLNP to DLNM1

0.010

0.008

0.006

0.004

0.002

0.000

-0.002

-0.004

2468101214161820

Response of DLNY to DLNM1

0.012

0.008

0.004

0.000

-0.004

-0.008

2468101214161820

Figure 7 Impulse Responses of Real Output and Price to Chinese M1 shocks

Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Response of DLNP to DLNM1

0.030

0.025

0.020

0.015

0.010

0.005

0.000

-0.005

2468101214161820

Response of DLNY to DLNM1

0.06

0.04

0.02

0.00

-0.02

-0.04

2468101214161820

The three-variable VAR may be subjected to omitted-variable bias since some relevant variables such as interest rate are not included. To examine the sensitivity of the above results, we augment the US case with the interest rate to get a four-variable VAR. The interest rate we use is Moody’s AAA series downloaded from https://www.wendangku.net/doc/8a18450557.html,. Similar to steps in section III, log(P) is first regressed on a constant, log(M1/Y) and interest rate to get the residuals as a measurement of the equilibrium relation. Then the four-variable VAR system is estimated and the corresponding impulse responses are plotted in Figure 8.

2018年同等学力申硕英语

2018年同等学力申硕英语 2018年同等学力申硕英语?面对同等学力考试,相信每一位考生都做好了充足的准备,相信每一位考生的心中各不相同。但是提醒考生切勿兴奋过头,要保持一颗清醒的头脑,冷静答题。尤其是英语考试,考生要注意一下几方面: 一、不要“抢”答,要做好答题前的准备 按照英语考试的组织规程,考试两个阶段正式开始答题前几分钟,同学们就会拿到英语试卷。首先要快速地整体浏览一下试卷,大致判断一下对于自己来说试卷的难度。这里要特别注意留意两个部分: 第一个是阅读理解,第二个是看一看书面表达题目 二、不要“长”答,要合理分配答题时间 在第一个阶段的英语考试中,控制好答题节奏,合理利用时间,这一点非常重要。不要在一道试题上耽误太多时间。阅读理解部分由于语篇多,词汇量和阅读量都大,因此比较耗时,但千万不能在这里“恋战”。 三、调动语感做到“一答”准确 英语考试考查语言的运用,因此,考试中有没有语感,就变得非常重要。答题时,不要一味地想语法,想考点,要把考试变成“调动语感”和进行“语言交流”。要自觉运用平时训练所形成的答题技巧。对应试卷各个题型,在回答问题时要注意:

(1)单项选择; (2)完型填空; (3)阅读理解; (4)翻译的重要一步就是一定要理解原文,然后在用自己的语言通顺的表达出来,英语重在意合,英语重在形合;(5)书面表达 四、仔细填涂答题卡避免“非能力失分” 英语考试不仅检验平时训练是否“有素”,“功力”是否“完满”,也体现临场发挥的程度和水平。 温馨提示:考试们在面对考试的时候不用有太多的担心,这2018年同等学力申硕英语其实英语考试除了考查学生英语知识,也是考查学生的应试能力,所以考生在考试中,一定要沉着冷静,保持一个稳定的心,希望同学们关注考试注意事项,注意答题的每一个细节,稳定心理,正常、甚至是超水平发挥,以期在考试中取得优异成绩。 附:在职研究生热门招生院校推荐表

2015同等学力申硕英语真题及参考答案(1)

2015年同等学力人员申请硕士学位外国语水平全国统一考试 英语试卷一、卷二真题及参考答案 考生须知 1.本考试分试卷一和试卷二两部分。试卷一满分75分,考试时间为100分钟, 9:00开始,10:40结束:试卷二满分25分,考试时间为50分钟,10:40开始,11:30结束。 2.请考生务必将本人姓名和考号填写在本页方框内。 3.请将试卷一答案用2B铅笔填涂在试卷一答题卡上,答在试卷上的无效。 4.在答题卡上正确的填涂方法为:在代表答案的字母上划线,如[A] [B][C][D]。 5.监考员宣布试卷一考试结束后,请停止答试卷一,将试卷一和试卷一答题卡反扣在自己的桌面上,继续做试卷二。监考员将到座位上收取试卷一和试卷一答题卡。 6.监考员收卷过程中,考生须配合监考员验收,并请监考员在准考证上签字(作为考生交卷的凭据),否则,若发生答卷遗失,责任由考生自负。 Paper One (100minutes) Part I Oral Communication (15 minutes,10 points) Section A Directions:In this section there are two incomplete dialogues and each dialogue has three blanks and three choices A,B and C,taken from the dialogue. Fill in each of the blanks with one of the choices to complete the dialogue and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Dialogue One A. Do you know what a handicapped space is? B. The signs always tell you how long you can park there and on what days. C. Then you also need to be aware of the time limits on the street signs. Student: Can you tell me where I can park? Clerk: Are you driving a motorcycle or an automobile? Student: I drive an automobile. Clerk: Fine. You can either park in the student lot or on the street. 1 Student: Yes, I have seen those spots. Clerk: Well, when you see the blue spots with the handicapped sign, do not park there unless you have a special permit. Are you going to be parking in the daytime or evening? Student: I park in the evenings. Clerk: 2 Have you seen those signs? Student: Yes, I have seen those signs. Clerk: 3 .

2015英语同等学力申硕真题及参考答案(4).docx

Part IV Cloze (10 points) Directions: In this part, there is a passage with ten blanks. For each blank there are four choices marked, A, B, C, and D. Choose the best answer for each blank and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. When asked about the impact of disturbing news on children, one mother said: “My 11-year-old daughter doesn’t like watching the news. She has 46 about what she has seen. One time, she watched a report about a person who killed a family member with a knife. That night she dreamed that she too was being killed.” Another interviewee said: “ My six-year-old niece saw reports of tornadoes(龙卷风)from elsewhere in the country. For weeks 47 , she was terrified. She 48 call me on the phone, convinced that a tornado was coming her way and that she was going to die.” Do you think disturbing news reports can frighten children? In one survey, nearly 40 percent of parents said that their children had been 49 by something they saw in the news and that, 50 , the children had feared that a similar event would happen to them or their loved ones. Why? One factor is that children often 51 the news differently from adults. For example, small children may believe that a 52 that is broadcast repeatedly is really happening repeatedly. A second factor is that daily reports of disturbing events can distort a child’s 53 of the world. True, we live in “critical times hard to 54 .” But repeated exposure to disturbing news reports can cause children to develop lasting fears. “Children who watch a lot of TV news 55 to overestimate the occurrence of crime and may perceive the world to be a more dangerous place than it actually is,” observes the Kaiser Family Foundation. 46. A. thoughts B. nightmares C. ideas D. pictures 47. A. afterward B. ago C. before D. later 48. A. should B. might C. could D. would 49. A. bored B. angered C. upset D. disappointed 50. A. in no time B. by all means C. all the more D. as a result 51. A. tell B. interpret C. narrate D. treat 52. A. tragedy B. comedy C. play D. drama 53. A. imagination B. view C. sight D. look 54. A. give up B. stick to C. deal with D. set down 55. A. prefer B. turn C. come D. tend 参考答案:46-50 BADCC 51-55 DABDD Part V Text Completion (20 points) Directions: In this part there are three incomplete texts with 20 questions (Ranging from 56 to 75).Above each text there are three or four phrases to be completed. First, use the choices provided in the box to complete the phrases. Second, use the completed phrases to fill in the blanks of the text. Mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Text One A. angrier B. getting C. action

2015年同等学力申硕英语真题

我们格外重视2016同等学力统考。 原因一,2016是同等学力30分漏洞的最后一年。自从有同等学力以来,考试大纲都是每4年一改,2013/2014/2015过去了,就只有2016了。 原因二,由于在职类中,同等学力的‘姐妹篇’GCT于2016并入了12月底的国家研究生统招考试,故2016的同等学力虽侥幸未并入其中,毋庸置疑难度肯定会同比加大。 原因三,2017同等学力的国家政策尚未明朗,如果届时同等学力也像GCT一样那就 惨了。据此,不管自身现有基础如何当然是越早备考越保险,切不可以胆试运,心存侥幸。一句话,试不起,也赌不起。因此,市面各培训机构学生购买各种辅导课程的数据显示,今年我们同等学力备考的学生也明显较往年早3-5个月不等。望备战2016同 等学力统考的同学们,即日起就投入到2016同等学力备考当中,但是切不可盲目选择辅导课程,除了要关注机构历年统考过关实情外(而非无法考实的过关率),还须充分试听相应辅导课程。你比如说英语科目,因为大家毕竟多年不接触英语了,各方面基础已忘乎殆尽,如果辅导课程不能帮助大家迅速获补基础,巧妙而直接的解决‘纯拼词汇语法题海式的传统备考方案’所带来的各种痛点,确实是很难确保帮助大家一次通关。不要忘了,2016是最后一年了! 2015年同等学力英语考试真题 Part I Oral Communication(10 points) Section A Directions: In this section there are two incomplete dialogues and each dialogue has three blanks and three choices A, B and C, taken from the dialogue. Fill in each of the blanks with one of the choices to complete

同等学力申硕英语如何有效进行复习

同等学力申硕英语如何有效进行复习? 近些年随着十月联考取消,报考同等学力申硕的人越来越多了,同等学力考试内容简单,但是英语很多人都不会复习,也不知道难度,下面小编为大家讲解一下, 同等学力申硕英语难度如何? 同等学力申硕的英语考试难度与四六级相当,所以是大家很容易通过的,但是也要注意对在职研究生英语单词的复习,首先大家要了解考研英语与四六级对词汇的要求不同。四六级考试是水平性考试,考试的目的是测验在校大学生的英语水平,直白的说,这种考试,是为了让大多数考生通过的,因此,词汇的复习要有针对性,把考研大纲5500个单词划分出个三六九等来,区别对待。对于你认为熟悉的初高中词汇,要重点记忆它的第二个,第三个,甚至第四个你不熟悉的意思。 同等学力申硕英语该如何复习? 每次都背单词 对于在职研究生英语单词,我们每天一百个是最低限,其实背到后来你会发现这个要求并不高,一个月后,你可能自然而然地就背到三百或者五百,时间上可以平均分配开来,第二天早晨复习以前没背下来的词。大家要一边看一边读每个词的读音,默读也成。看完后回忆一遍,回忆不起来的再看。 多和单词“约会”

对于在职研究生英语单词是否“一见钟情”都是无所谓的,关键在于有更多不同类型的见面机会,因为一个单词能不能记住,取决于和它在不同场合见面的频率,不在于每次看着它的时间长短。一般想记住一个单词,每星期要和它在不同场合见三到四次面,具体问题一定要具体分析;另外,大家在背单词时,还要把握住最基础的部分,也就是所谓的词根,对付这些词根的最好方法,就是进行大量的,不间断的,简单的初级听力练习。因为阅读材料中,还有百分之二十其他词汇,所以光凭这个等级的词还看不懂那些阅读材料。 附:在职研究生热门招生院校推荐表

最新同等学力申硕英语大纲学习资料

同等学力人员申请硕士学位英语水平全 国统一考试大纲(第六版) 一、指导思想 本考试大纲要求通过 教学使学生具有较好的用英语获取信息的能 力和一定的用英语传递信息的能力。这就要求考生具有较强的阅读理解能力,一定的口语交际能力和语篇信息处理能力,同时也必须具有一定的英译汉能力和写作能力。本考试旨在测试考生是否达到大纲所规定的各项要求和具 有大纲所规定的各项语言运用能力。 二、评价目标 本考试重点考查考生的英语口 语交际、阅读、语篇完形处理、英译汉和写作等技能(由于技术上的原因,本考试暂时取消听力测试,口语交际技能的测试采用书面形式进行。考生听力能力的测试由各院校在考生学习期间进行)。考生应在词汇知识、语法知识、口语交际能力、阅读理解能力、语篇完形处理

能力、英译汉能力和写作能力等方面分别达到以下要求: (一)词汇 掌握约6 000个英语词汇和约700个常用词组。对6 000个词汇中的2 800个左右的积极词汇要求熟练掌握,即能在口语交际和写作中准确地运用;其余词汇则要求能在阅读、语篇完形处理和英译汉等过程中识别和理解。 (二)语法 掌握英语的基本语法知识、常用句型和结构,能正确理解包含这些知识、句型和结构的句子和语篇。 (三)口语交际 能用英语进行日常口语交流。对于生活、学习和工作中的常见英语交流,能理解交流情景、说话人的意图和会话的含义,并能运用相应的知识和判断进行恰当的交流。能正确理解英语口语中常见的习惯用法。

(四)阅读 能综合运用英语语言知识和阅 读技能读懂一般性题材的文章、广告等应用性文本和博客及跟帖等互动形式的阅读材料。要求能抓住大 意,读懂细节,能理解上下文的逻辑关系,并能领会和分辨作者或话语参与各方的主要 意图和态度及其异同等。 (五)语篇完形处理 在理解阅读材料的基础上能综 合运用词汇、语法、搭配、语段、篇章逻辑等方面的知识和上下文等对语篇各层次的信息 进行正确判断和完型处理。 (六)英译汉 能在不借助词典的情况下,把一般性题材的文章及科普文章中的段落从英语 译成汉语,能准确表达原文的意思,语句通顺,用词基本正确,无重大语言错误。 (七)写作

同等学力申硕英语大纲

同等学力人员申请硕士学位英语水平全国统一考试大纲(第六版) 一、指导思想 本考试大纲要求通过教学使学生具有较好的用英语获取信息的能力和一定的用英语传递信息的能力。这就要求考生具有较强的阅读理解能力,一定的口语交际能力和语篇信息处理能力,同时也必须具有一定的英译汉能力和写作能力。本考试旨在测试考生是否达到大纲所规定的各项要求和具有大纲所规定的各项语言运用能力。 二、评价目标 本考试重点考查考生的英语口语交际、阅读、语篇完形处理、英译汉和写作等技能(由于技术上的原因,本考试暂时取消听力测试,口语交际技能的测试采用书面形式进行。考生听力能力的测试由各院校在考生学习期间进行)。考生应在词汇知识、语法知识、口语交际能力、阅读理解能力、语篇完形处理能力、英译汉能力和写作能力等方面分别达到以下要求: (一)词汇 掌握约6 000个英语词汇和约700个常用词组。对6 000个词汇中的2 800个左右的积极词汇要求熟练掌握,即能在口语交际和写作中准确地运用;其余词汇则要求能在阅读、语篇完形处理和英译汉等过程中识别和理解。 (二)语法 掌握英语的基本语法知识、常用句型和结构,能正确理解包含这些知识、句型和结构的句子和语篇。 (三)口语交际 能用英语进行日常口语交流。对于生活、学习和工作中的常见英语交流,能理解交流情景、说话人的意图和会话的含义,并能运用相应的知识和判断进行恰当的交流。能正确理解英语口语中常见的习惯用法。 (四)阅读 能综合运用英语语言知识和阅读技能读懂一般性题材的文章、广告等应用性文本和博客及跟帖等互动形式的阅读材料。要求能抓住大 意,读懂细节,能理解上下文的逻辑关系,并能领会和分辨作者或话语参与各方的主要意图和态度及其异同等。 (五)语篇完形处理

同等学力申硕英语备考经验汇总

在职研究生同等学力申硕英语备考经验汇总 一、复习方法篇 1、如何高效增加词汇量 1)不要背书 大部分人背书都是背了后面忘了前面,正襟危坐几个小时,其实记住的单词没几个,为什么?因为人的瞬时记忆力只能记忆5-7个东西,比如你妈妈叫你去买菜,七样以内你能记住,要是十几样你就得用笔记了。因此背书没用,那怎么办?就是分组背,记一组,测试一组,再记下一组。(刘毅的背单词的书就是按照这个原理来设计的) 2)不要用整段时间来背单词 我看过很多人的每日计划,什么几点到几点是背单词时间。这个没用,你花几个小时光背单词,记忆效率绝对很低,脑袋都木掉,合上书一个字也想不起来。一些英语牛人就一个背单词方法——小卡片。每天没事就拿出来看一下,坚持不懈,效果绝对好。 3)在遗忘临界点复习 有个伟大的艾宾浩斯记忆曲线,非常厉害,只要按照那个曲线在遗忘临界点复习,5次复习就可以终身不忘。可以在第1、2、5、15、30、60天把单词再重复看一遍! 4)语境记忆 背单词绝对不能没有例句,中文的一个词你可以对他有很多种解释,英文也一样,如果没有例句帮你体会单词用法,光背词意在真正阅读的时候一定会抓瞎。(刘毅的背单词的书每个单词都有例句) 5)巧用学习工具 现在科技发达,学习工具很多,巧加利用才能事半功倍。我用的是Nokia N73手机,里面有英汉词典,遇到不懂的单词随时用来查,同时也可以把一些单词作为提示有空的时候拿来看。 6)背记单词必须和做真题结合起来 因为单词必须得放到文章中能够认知才叫记住了单词这样单词的记忆会达到事半功倍的效果。传统的每天只是拿着单词书死记硬背是不科学的也是效率最低的。

在单词有了进步之后,你会发现不管是汉译英还是英译汉都不在害怕。但是前提仍然是,多多练习。熟能生巧,翻译多了,跟好的翻译答案对照之后,你会发现好多“的字结构”“使字结构”“无主句”等等之类的句子其实翻译方法是很有章可循的,翻译多了,你会知道什么情况下用被动结构,什么情况下用强调结构,这些能力的前提是必须得多多练习。 2、疯狂做往年的真题并且做后花长时间认真分析 认真做每年的真题,尤其是一些有考验经验的人推荐的真题。争取三天一套,做的时候要卡着时间。做完后要理科对照着正确答案认真分析。做完一套真题可能只需要三个小时的时间,但是做完之后的分析却需要6个小时。所以按照在职学习人的时间来算,三天做一套真题节奏刚好。即便是你做过一遍之后,答案已经背下来了,也仍然要认认真真地做真题,把真题的阅读理解和完形填空作为精读的材料去认真详细地分析每一个句子,攻下你在真题里碰到的每一个生词。 做真题有几大好处,一是通过反复做真题,你可以记住大纲里80%的单词;二是通过反复做真题,你可以熟悉阅读理解完形填空的文章风格和真题出题思路,到考试的时候才不会不适应,尤其是近5年的试题;三是真题的阅读理解其实就是很好很地道的说明文和议论文,熟读之后你会发现里面有好多很精美很地道的句子,拿来用到自己的作文里非常的出彩。三是通过精读真题的阅读理解和完形填空,基本上你第二卷的英译汉已经不成问题了。(第二卷的作文和英译汉通过做真题完全可以搞定了)。 3、针对09新大纲复习对策 今年的英语考试大纲试卷一考试内容与以往相比,去掉了辨识错误部分,保留了会话技能、词汇、阅读理解、综合填空4部分内容。也就是说在考试时间不变的情况下,考试内容减少,试卷难度也就相应降低,对考生而言是好消息。以往,辨错题是试卷中唯一直接考查语法结构题目,新大纲调整后,考生就不需要记忆细小语法知识,更利于考生的英语复习。 专家认为辨识错误部分的5分可能会加到阅读理解部分或词汇部分。根据新大纲中的样题看,2009年英语考试阅读理解部分分值预计会增加,由25分变成30分,题目数量也相应从25个增至30个。同时,新大纲删除500多个旧词增加1220多个新词和50个常用词组。词汇量要求提高预示着今年的英语水平考试难度可能比以往会加大。 面对新大纲词汇量增加的问题,考生可以采用像滚雪球一样的方法记忆。在复习词汇时,首先从掌握大学英语四六级考试要求的词汇入手,每天定时定量地完成背诵内容,第二天,将学过的单词默写几遍,以加深印象。这个阶段大概需要3个月的时间,然后进入背诵考研词汇阶段,考生可选择一本考研核心词汇作为辅助记忆参考书。但是不要认为单词一遍就记住了,记单词的关键是重复记忆。按照记忆曲线,记忆7次一般就差不多记住了,但是还有很少的一部分单词不能记住。他在记完7次以后,把仍然记不住的单词抄在卡片上。正面写着英文单词、词性、音标;背面写着意思、助记法等。

2013同等学力申硕考试英语真题及答案

2013同等学力申硕考试英语真题及答案

2013同等学力申硕考试英语真题(A卷) 英语试卷一 Paper One (100minutes) Part I Oral Communication (15 minutes,10 points) Section A Directions:In this section there are two incomplete dialogues and each dialogue has three blanks and three choices A,B and C,taken from the dialogue. Fill in each of the blanks with one of the choices to complete the dialogue and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Dialogue one A. It sounds like a flu. B. I also advise resting for a couple of days. C. Boy, when it rains, it pours. Doctor: What has been bothering you? Patient: I have a stuffy nose and a sore throat. Plus, I’ve been coughing a lot. 1 Doctor: Any stomach pains? Patient: Actually, yes. My stomach’s been upset for a few days. Doctor: 2 . It’s been going around lately. Patient: Anything I can do for it? Doctor: I’ll prescribe some medicines for you to take. 3 . Patient: Does that mean I shouldn’t go to work? Doctor: Only when you feel up to it. You should stay home for at least a day or two. Dialogue Two A. So, what are you going to do with the money? B. You have lots of money. C. How much do I owe you? Joshua: Dad. Allowance day. Can I have my allowance? Father: Oh, I forgot about that. Joshua: You ALWAYS forget. Father: I guess I do. 4 Joshua: Just $13. Father: Well, I’ m not sure if I have that much. Joshua: Go to bank. 5 Father: Lots of money, uh? Uh, well, I think the bank is closed. Joshua: Then, what about your secret money jar under your bed? Father: Oh, I guess I could do that. 6 Joshua: I ’m going to put some in savings, give some to the poor people, and use the rest to buy books.

2013同等学力申硕考试英语真题及答案

2013同等学力申硕考试英语真题(A卷) 英语试卷一 Paper One (100minutes) Part I Oral Communication (15 minutes,10 points) Section A Directions:In this section there are two incomplete dialogues and each dialogue has three blanks and three choices A,B and C,taken from the dialogue. Fill in each of the blanks with one of the choices to complete the dialogue and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Dialogue one A. It sounds like a flu. B. I also advise resting for a couple of days. C. Boy, when it rains, it pours. Doctor: What has been bothering you? Patient: I have a stuffy nose and a sore throat. Plus, I’ve been coughing a lot. 1 Doctor: Any stomach pains? Patient: Actually, yes. My stomach’s been upset for a few days. Doctor: 2 . It’s been going around lately. Patient: Anything I can do for it? Doctor: I’ll prescribe some medicines for you to take. 3 . Patient: Does that mean I shouldn’t go to work? Doctor: Only when you feel up to it. You should stay home for at least a day or two. Dialogue Two A. So, what are you going to do with the money? B. You have lots of money. C. How much do I owe you? Joshua: Dad. Allowance day. Can I have my allowance? Father: Oh, I forgot about that. Joshua: You ALWAYS forget. Father: I guess I do. 4 Joshua: Just $13. Father: We ll, I’ m not sure if I have that much. Joshua: Go to bank. 5 Father: Lots of money, uh? Uh, well, I think the bank is closed. Joshua: Then, what about your secret money jar under your bed? Father: Oh, I guess I could do that. 6 Joshua: I ’m going to put some in savings, give some to the poor people, and use the rest to buy books. Father: Well, that sounds greats great, Joshua.

英语同等学力申硕真题及参考答案

Part III Reading Comprehension (25 points) Section A Directions: In this section, there are four passages followed by questions or unfinished statements, each with four suggested answers A, B, C and D. Choose the best answer and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Passage One Sometimes a race is not enough. Sometimes a runner just wants to go further. That’s what happened to Dennis Martin and Brooke Curran. Martin, 68, a retired detective form New York City, took up running after his first wife died. Curran, 46, a philanthropist(慈善家)from Alexandria, started running to get out of the house and collect her thoughts. Both she and Martin got good at running but felt the desire to do more. “The more I trained, the better I got,” Curran said,” but I would cross the finish line with no sense of accomplishment.”Eventually , they worked up to running marathons(马拉松)(and longer races) in other countries, on other countries. Now both have achieved a notable -and increasingly less rate- milestone; running the 26.2-mile race on all seven continents. They are part of a phenomenon that has grown out of the running culture in the past two decades, at the intersection of athleticism and leisure: “runcations,”which combine distance running with travel to exotic places. There trips, as expensive as they are physically challenging ,are a growing and competitive market in the travel industry. “In the beginning, running was enough,” said Steen Albrechtsen, a press manager. The classic marathon was the ultimate goal, then came the super marathons, like London and New York. But when 90,000 people a year can take that challenge, it is no longer e xciting and adventurous .Hence, the search for new adventures began.”“No one could ever have imagined that running would become the lifestyle activity that it is today,”said Thom Gilligan, founder and president of Boston-based Marathon Tours and Travel. Gilligan, who has been in business since 1979, is partly responsible for the seven-continent phenomenon. It started with a casual talk to an interviewer about his company offering trips to every continent except Antarctica. And then in 1995, Marathon fours hosted its first Antarctica Marathon on King George Island. Off the tip of the Antarctic Peninsula; 160 runners got to the starting line of a dirt-and ice-trail route via a Russian icebreaker through the Drake Passage. 21. At the beginning, Martin took up running just to . A. meet requirements of his job B. win a running race C. join in a philanthropic activity D. get away from his sadness 22. Martin and Curran are mentioned as good examples of . A. winners in the 26.2-mile race on all seven continents B. people who enjoy long running as a lifestyle activity C. running racers satisfied with their own performance

2015年同等学力申硕考试英语真题

2015年同等学力申硕考试英语真题 Part I Oral Communication(10 points) Section A Directions: In this section there are two incomplete dialogues and each dialogue has three blanks and three choices A, B and C, taken from the dialogue. Fill in each of the blanks with one of the choices to complete the dialogue and mark your answer on the Answer Sheet. Dialogue One A.Do you know what a handicapped space is ? B.The signs always tell you how long you can park there and on what days. C.Then you also need to be aware of the time limits on the street signs. Student: Can you tell me where I can park? Clerk: Are you driving a motorcycle or an automobile? Student: I drive an automobile. Clerk: Fine.You can either park in the student lot or on the street. 1 Student: Yes,I have seen those spots. Clerk: well,when you see the blue spots with the handicapped sign, do not park there unless you have a special permit.Are you going to be parking in the daytime or evening? Student: I park in the evenings. Clerk: 2 Have you seen those signs? Student: Yes ,I have seen those signs. Clerk: 3 Dialogue Two A. The hours and limitations are printed on the card and this handout. B. May I have your driver's license,please? C. Are you familiar with our rules and fines? Student:Excuse me,I am interested in getting a library card. Librarian:Sure,let me give you an application.You can fill it out right here at the counter. Student: Thank you.I'll do it right now. Librarian:Let me take a look at this for you. 4 Student : Here it is. Librarian : You seem to have filled the form out all right.___5___ Student : Yes.I know what to do. Librarian : ____6____ Student : OK . I see. Librarian : Thank you for joining the library; We look forward to serving you. Section B Directions: In this section there is one incomplete which has four blanks and four choices A,B,C and D , taken from the interview . Fill in each of the blanks

同等学力申硕英语词汇练习及答案

同等学力人员申请硕士学位英语水平考试词汇练习 选择替换题及答案 (1)I’m in a position to think about my future and plan it a little more rather than just waiting for what happens. A.used to B.unwilling to C.able to D.glad to (2) The Canadian landscape painters’ style featured brilliant colors and free brushstrokes. A.furthered B.showed C.replaced D.excluded (3) Milton Hershey was a successful entrepreneur whose openhearted generosity continues to touch the lives of thousands. A.generation B.kindness C.faculty D.readiness (4) Green plants take in carbon dioxide and give off oxygen in a food-making process called photosynthesis. A.donate B.check C.withhold D.release (5) The discovery of gold fields has long attracted large numbers of prospectors and other people because of the traditionally high value of gold. A.searchers B.inspectors C.protectors D.instructors (6) Even our Mitsubishi four-wheel-drive truck gets altitude sickness once in a while,so we like to give her a rest whenever we can. A.sometimes B.usually C.often D.seldom (7)Sculptors from Pergamum developed a distinct style,which they employed in creating a magnificent altar dedicated to Zeus,king of the Greek gods.A.set up B.carved up C.devoted to D.1ed to (8)Working where there is no running water causes a lot of suffering.Fortunately we have a cold spring a short distance from our house. A.Forgivably B.Steadily C.Constantly D.Luckily (9)The research shows that nearly 130 species of birds are vulnerable to the predicted effects of climate change. A.easily attacked by B.skillfully adapted to C.comfortably inclined to D.closely involved in (10)On the grounds of Wimbledon,a year-round museum is devoted to the joys and history of the sport—and one of their current exhibits showcases Ted Tinling,the popular and controversial designer of tennis dresses. A.conflicting B.well-known

相关文档
相关文档 最新文档